Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-45l2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T13:50:17.505Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Middlemen: good for resources and fishermen?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 July 2019

Phạm Thị Thanh Thủy*
Affiliation:
Norwegian College of Fishery Science, University of Tromsø – The Arctic University of Norway, Tromsø, Norway Faculty of Economics, University of Nha Trang, Khánh Hòa, Vietnam
Ola Flaaten
Affiliation:
Norwegian College of Fishery Science, University of Tromsø – The Arctic University of Norway, Tromsø, Norway
Anders Skonhoft
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Norwegian University of Science and Technology, Trondheim, Norway
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: thanh.thuy@uit.no

Abstract

This paper studies the role of middlemen in open-access fisheries and how the organization of the supply chains affects resource exploitation and the level and distribution of economic rent. Imperfect competition among middlemen can help ensure that fish stocks are not depleted, which is typically the case in open-access fisheries with competitive markets. Middlemen with market power can also induce higher economic rent for the supply chain in total, but these rents mainly benefit the middlemen. The supply chains of inshore anchovy and offshore skipjack tuna fisheries in Vietnam are used as empirical examples. The analysis shows that in the anchovy supply chain, the middlemen have insignificant market power and the stock is being overexploited. In the skipjack tuna supply chain, the middlemen have oligopsony power and the stock is higher than the level that produces maximum sustainable yield.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Andersen, P, Cheng, F, Frandsen, S, Kuyvenhoven, A and Braun, JV (2009) Case Studies in Food Policy for Developing Countries: Domestic Policies for Markets, Production, and Environment. New York: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Arya, A, Loffler, C, Mittendorf, B and Pfeiffer, T (2015) The middleman as a panacea for supply chain coordination problems. European Journal of Operational Research 240, 393400.Google Scholar
Asche, F, Flaaten, O, Isaksen, JR and Vassdal, T (2002) Derived demand and relationships between prices at different levels in the value chain: a note. Journal of Agricultural Economics 53, 101107.Google Scholar
Asche, F, Jaffry, S and Hartmann, J (2007) Price transmission and market integration: vertical and horizontal price linkages for salmon. Applied Economics 39, 25352545.Google Scholar
Béné, C, Hersoug, B and Allison, EH (2010) Not by rent alone: analyzing the pro-poor functions of small-scale fisheries in developing countries. Development Policy Review 28, 325358.Google Scholar
Clark, CW (2007) The Worldwide Crisis in Fisheries Economic Models and Human Behavior. London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Clark, CW and Munro, GR (1980) Fisheries and the processing sector: some implications for management policy. The Bell Journal of Economics 11, 603616.Google Scholar
Coglan, L and Pascoe, S (1999) Separating resource rents from intra-marginal rents in fisheries economic survey data. Agricultural Resource Economics Review 28, 219228.Google Scholar
Copes, P (1970) The backward-bending supply curve of the fishing industry. Scottish Journal Political Economy 17, 6977.Google Scholar
Copes, P (1972) Factor rents, sole ownership and the optimum level of fisheries exploitation. Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies 40, 145163.Google Scholar
Crona, B, Nyström, M, Folke, C and Jiddawi, N (2010) Middlemen, a critical social-ecological link in coastal communities of Kenya and Zanzibar. Marine Policy 34, 761771.Google Scholar
Crutchfield, JA and Pontecorvo, G (1969) The Pacific Salmon Fishery: A Study of Irrational Conservation. Baltimore: John Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Duy, NN, Kim Anh, NT and Tram Anh, NT (2012a) Balancing benefits between fishermen and actors in supply chains of capture fish products: the case of skipjack tuna in Khanh Hoa. (In Vietnamese: Hài hoà lợi ích giữa ngư dân và các tác nhân trong chuỗi giá trị sản phẩm thuỷ sản khai thác-Trường hợp mặt hàng cá ngừ sọc dưa tại Khánh Hoà.) Science and Technology Journal of Agriculture and Rural Development 6, 1119.Google Scholar
Duy, NN, Flaaten, O, Kim Anh, NT and Ngoc, QTK (2012b) Open-access fishing rent and efficiency – the case of gillnet vessels in Nha Trang, Vietnam. Fisheries Research 127–128, 98108.Google Scholar
Flaaten, O (2018) Fisheries Economics and Management, 2nd edn. Tromso: The Norwegian College of Fishery Science, University of Tromsø.Google Scholar
Flaaten, O and Schulz, CE (2010) Triple win for trade in renewable resource goods by use of export taxes. Ecological Economics 69, 10761082.Google Scholar
Flaaten, O, Heen, K and Matthíasson, T (2017) Profit and resource rent in fisheries. Marine Resource Economics 32, 311328.Google Scholar
Gordon, HS (1954) The economic theory of a common property resource: the fishery. Journal of Political Economy 62, 124142.Google Scholar
Gudmundsson, E, Asche, F and Nielsen, M (2006) Revenue distribution through the seafood chain. FAO Fisheries Circular No. 1019. Available at http://www.fao.org/docrep/009/a0564e/a0564e00.htm.Google Scholar
Halsema, A and Withagen, C (2008) Managing multiple fishery pools: property rights regimes and market structures. Environment and Development Economics 13, 775794.Google Scholar
Hannesson, R (2000) Renewable resources and the gains from trade. Canadian Journal of Economics 33, 122132.Google Scholar
Hardin, G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science 162, 1630.Google Scholar
Homans, FR and Wilen, JE (1997) A model of regulated open access resource use. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 32, 121.Google Scholar
Homans, FR and Wilen, JE (2005) Markets and rent dissipation in regulated open access fisheries. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 49, 381404.Google Scholar
Kronbak, LG, Squires, D and Vestergaard, N (2014) Recent developments in fisheries economics research. International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics 7, 67108.Google Scholar
MARD (2018) Annual Report to the Western and Central Pacific Fisheries Commission. Hanoi, Vietnam: Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development.Google Scholar
Masters, A (2008) Unpleasant middlemen. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 68, 7386.Google Scholar
Munro, GR and Scott, AD (1985) The economics of fisheries management. In Knesse, AV and Sweeney, JL (eds). Handbook of Natural Resource and Energy Economics, vol 2. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 623676.Google Scholar
Nielsen, M (2006) Trade liberalisation, resource sustainability and welfare: the case of East Baltic cod. Ecological Economics 58, 650664.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E (1990) Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E (2009) A general framework for analyzing sustainability of social-ecological systems. Science 325, 419422.Google Scholar
Quaas, MF, Stoeven, MT, Klauere, B, Petersen, T and Schiller, J (2018) Windows of opportunity for sustainable fisheries management: the case of Eastern Baltic cod. Environmental and Resource Economics 70, 323341.Google Scholar
Sapkota, P, Dey, MM, Alam, MdF and Singh, K (2015) Price transmission relationships along the seafood value chain in Bangladesh: aquaculture and capture fisheries. Aquaculture Economics and Management 19, 82103.Google Scholar
Schworm, WE (1983) Monopsonistic control of a common property renewable resource. Canadian Journal of Economics 16, 275287.Google Scholar
Tan, PN (2015) Analysis of anchovy value chain in Khanh Hoa province. (In Vietnamese: Phân tích chuỗi giá trị cá cơm tỉnh Khánh Hòa.) Master thesis, Nha Trang University, Nha Trang, Vietnam.Google Scholar
Thi, DV, Bat, NK, Nguyen, DV, Anh, PV, Nghia, NV, Ha, VV, and Thanh, ND (2007) Anchovy stock assessment in southwest Vietnam, and the solutions for sustainable management. (In Vietnamese: Đánh giá nguồn lợi cá Cơm (Stolephorus spp.) ở vùng biển Tây Nam Bộ và đề xuất các giải pháp bảo vệ, khai thác hợp lý.) Research Institute of Marine Fisheries, Hai Phong, Vietnam.Google Scholar
Thurman, WN and Easley, J Jr (1992) Valuing changes in commercial fishery harvests: a general equilibrium derived demand analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 22, 226240.Google Scholar
Thuy, TTP and Flaaten, O (2013) The backward-bending supply curve revisited. Journal of Sustainable Development 6, 1533.Google Scholar
Wallis, P and Flaaten, O (2003) Fisheries management costs – concepts and studies. In Schrank, WE, Arnason, R and Hannesson, R (eds). The Cost of Fisheries Management. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate Publishing Ltd, pp. 211223.Google Scholar
WTO (2010) World Trade Report 2010: Trade in Natural Resources. Available at http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/publications_e/wtr10_e.htm.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Thủy et al. supplementary material

Thủy et al. supplementary material 1

Download Thủy et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 264.2 KB