Elsevier

Marine Policy

Volume 36, Issue 5, September 2012, Pages 1044-1046
Marine Policy

Raising the “Sunken Billions”: Financing the transition to sustainable fisheries

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.marpol.2012.02.020Get rights and content

Abstract

Long-term investment to drive the adoption of precautionary, adaptive and resilience-building fisheries management measures is urgently required, especially given the financially difficult transition period to reach sustainable fisheries. In this paper a case for investing in the recovery of large marine ecosystems is provided based on the future value of recovered fish stocks. It is argued that the current market-based sustainable seafood movement alone will not affect the scale of change needed and must be complemented by investment in fundamental conservation measures that will lead to the recovery of marine ecosystems and promote long-term sustainable use. A rationale for addressing the economically challenging transition period is provided and the basis of a new financial institution to finance the measures necessary for realising the economic, social and environmental benefits of large-scale fisheries reform is proposed.

Highlights

► Financially difficult transition periods often prevent fisheries from achieving sustainability. ► Market based incentives alone are unlikely to affect recovery at the ecosystem scale necessary. ► A case is proposed for the creation of a “Financial Institution for the Recovery of Marine Ecosystems”. ► The purpose is to invest in conservation of the biodiversity and habitats on which fisheries depend. ► Redirected government subsidies and private financing could create incentives for change.

Introduction

The economic and social importance of healthy, functioning marine ecosystems are well understood [1], yet the world’s oceans have suffered many decades of excessive fishing pressure that has eroded the natural capital base on which an increasing demand for seafood is dependent [2], [3], [4]. While positive fisheries management changes are occurring in some large marine ecosystems (e.g., Gulf of Alaska, New Zealand Shelf), these are the exception rather than the rule. The ocean faces unprecedented levels of large-scale, multiple stresses from warming and acidifying seas as a result of climate change and pollution [5], but fisheries impacts have long been the single most important contributing factor in the decline of marine biodiversity.

Recognition of these serious risks to global oceans led to international commitments made in 1992 (United Nations Conference on the Environment and Development) and 2002 (World Summit on Sustainable Development) to improve management of marine resources. Despite this, in 2010 the number of fisheries reported to be ‘fully exploited’ or ‘over exploited, depleted, recovering from depletion’ rose to 85%. Around the same period (2008), a new record in seafood demand was recorded at 17 kg live weight equivalent of fish per person [6]. With human population projections being as much as 10.6 billion by 2050 [7], seafood demand has a clear upward trajectory.

The failure to adequately invest in recovery and sustainable use of fisheries not only includes the well-publicized environmental and social consequences, but lost economic benefits too. The World Bank and FAO estimated that losses due to inefficient fisheries is around $50 billion annually with the cumulative loss over the past three decades around $2 trillion [8]. These numbers represent recoverable losses to one of the most widely traded food commodities with exports worth more than $85 billion in 2008 [9] and related economic activity generated in the range of $500 billion per year [7].

Capture fisheries are a unique category of the food industry as the energy inputs for producing fish are wholly subsidized by nature. It thus makes good economic sense to minimize capture costs and to harvest sustainably [10], providing the potential for fish stocks to feed the world indefinately. To meet this need, long-term investment to drive the adoption of precautionary, adaptive and resilience-building fisheries management measures is urgently required. The key issue is how the potential benefits can be realized, given the financially difficult transition period that currently inhibits fisheries reform [11]. Here, this fundamental challenge is addressed by proposing an institutional arrangement that is designed to finance fisheries management reform and biodiversity conservation, when combined with good governance and market-based incentives.

Section snippets

Beyond the market place

Market demand for certified sustainable seafood can be a powerful agent for change and is becoming increasingly prevalent in the marketplace. The Marine Stewardship Council (MSC), for example, currently has “just under 10,000 individual product lines in a global market for labelled certified seafood now worth over $2.5 billion annually” [12]. Improvements in fishing practices resulting from conditions imposed on certified fisheries can certainly help mitigate fisheries impacts on the broader

Enabling conditions

The problem of transitional costs is well recognized. Numerous injections of investment capital, typically sourced from government or foundation grants with little or no expected financial return, have financed schemes to safeguard marine biodiversity. Increasingly, social finance in both non-profit and for-profit social and environmental enterprises, including blended investments from a range of sources, has provided at least a nominal financial return. However, while many fishery

Public/private funding pathways

One of the most significant and ready sources of investment capital could be that acquired by redirecting harmful fisheries subsidies. A recent study by Sumaila et al. [19] estimated that global fisheries subsidies for 2003 were between $25 and $29 billion, of which $16 billion was used to enhance capacity – one of the principal drivers of over-fishing. Clearly government subsidies are effectively funding the over-exploitation of marine resources by an industry that would otherwise be

Conclusion

The FIRME provides an approach that could derive momentum from a growing consensus on solutions for our oceans e.g., [23] and the need for political commitments on the ‘green economy’ theme (e.g., United Nations Conference on Sustainable Development UNCSD/Rio +20). In 2010 at Nagoya, the Conference of the Parties (COP10) of the UN Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD) identified the need for innovative financing to underpin sustainability investments in nature. Meeting that challenge with

Acknowledgments

The authors acknowledge the contributions of many individuals who helped shape our ideas during numerous consultations hosted by WWF. In addition, we are greatly indebted to staff at the Prince’s Charities’ International Sustainability Unit (Charlotte Cawthorne, Jack Gibbs, John Goodlad) and to the participants of ISU hosted workshops. Thanks also to: Tim Bostock (The World Bank); Ian Glew (Memorial University of Newfoundland); Jeffrey Hutchings (Dalhousie University); Astrid Scholz (Ecotrust);

References (23)

  • R.W.D. Davies et al.

    Banking on Cod: Exploring economic incentives for recovering Grand Banks and North Sea cod populations

    Marine Policy

    (2010)
  • B. Worm et al.

    Impacts of biodoversity loss on ocean ecosystem services

    Science

    (2006)
  • T.B. Essington et al.

    Fishing through marine food webs

    Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. U.S.A.

    (2006)
  • Munro, G.R. The Economics of rebuilding fisheries. OECD Workshop proceedings. April 2010. ISBN: 9789264075412; OECD...
  • P. Pauly et al.

    Fishing down marine food webs

    Science

    (1998)
  • A.D. Rogers et al.

    International Earth system expert workshop on ocean stresses and impacts

    Summary Report

    (2011)
  • FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture Department. ”The state of the world fisheries and aquaculture”. Food and Agricultural...
  • United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs: Population Division. “World Population to 2300”. New York:...
  • The World Bank Washington, D.C., United Nations Food and Agricultural Organisation. ”The Sunken billions—the economic...
  • A.J. Dyck et al.

    Economic impact of global fish populations in the global fishery

    J Bioeconomics

    (2010)
  • OECD-FAO AGRICULTURAL OUTLOOK 2011-2020 © OECD/FAO 2011....
  • Cited by (12)

    • Financial aspects of marine economic growth: From the perspective of coastal provinces and regions in China

      2021, Ocean and Coastal Management
      Citation Excerpt :

      Spergel and Moye (2004) studied how to raise funds to improve marine biodiversity and proposed dozens of specific financing measures. Furthermore, Rangeley and Davies (2012) believe that a new fishery financial institution needs to be established to achieve comprehensive economic, social and environmental benefits. In another instance, Tengberg and Cabanban (2013) found that financial institutions at all levels, from local to national, should introduce corresponding measures to strengthen marine ecosystem protection.

    • Marine conservation finance: The need for and scope of an emerging field

      2015, Ocean and Coastal Management
      Citation Excerpt :

      In most cases, however, offsets have not been managed well enough to prevent net environmental losses, which occur when the financial requirement is too small to compensate for environmental damage and/or compensation for damage is not scientifically or practically possible (Bos et al., 2014). An old idea that has recently gained significant momentum is re-directing perverse subsidies such as those for fisheries (Rangeley and Davies, 2012; EDF et al., 2014) and agriculture (Evans et al., 2012) towards more sustainable enterprises. Investors in subsidies can include governments (who source funds from the public through taxes and other finance mechanisms), philanthropists, or private companies.

    • From cod to shellfish and back again? The new resource geography and Newfoundland's fish economy

      2013, Applied Geography
      Citation Excerpt :

      The World Bank/FAO analysis found that the global fish industry was losing $50 billion annually due to the mismanagement of fish resources. The report predicted that $2 trillion could be earned over the next three decades if fish resources were harvested sustainably (Rangeley & Davies, 2012). These two principles – the limits of market based approaches and the economic potential of fish resources – form the foundation for the WWF's new approach to fish stock recovery.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text