Elsevier

Journal of Monetary Economics

Volume 63, April 2014, Pages 95-106
Journal of Monetary Economics

The contribution of rising school quality to U.S. economic growth

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2014.01.006Get rights and content

Highlights

  • This paper explores how much U.S. labor quality grew due to rising school quality.

  • A schooling model and cohort-variations in earnings are used for identification.

  • U.S. labor quality increased by 0.4% per year between 1967 and 2000.

  • One-fifth of the labor quality growth is attributable to the rise in school spending.

  • Labor quality growth explains one-quarter of the growth in U.S. labor productivity.

Abstract

U.S. public school expenditures per pupil increased by a factor of 9 during the 20th century. This paper quantifies how much U.S. labor quality has grown due to the rise in educational spending. A schooling model and cross-sectional earnings variations across cohorts are exploited to identify the effect of the increased school expenditures on labor quality growth. The findings are that (i) U.S. labor quality increased by 0.4% per year between 1967 and 2000, one-fifth of which is attributable to the rise in educational spending; and (ii) labor quality growth explains one-quarter of the rise in labor productivity.

Introduction

During the 20th century, the real spending per pupil in U.S. public elementary and secondary schools increased by a factor of 9. This paper explores how much U.S. labor quality has grown due to the rise in school expenditures. The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) currently measures labor quality growth mainly based on increases in the mean years of schooling but fails to capture the impact of changes in the quality of education. If the increased educational expenditures improved school quality, then the BLS underestimates the growth in U.S. labor quality.

This paper proposes a new way of quantifying the rise in the quality of education with a schooling model in which human capital production depends not only on time in school but also on educational spending. This model as well as cross-sectional earnings variations across cohorts is exploited to identify the growth in school quality. Consider cross-sectional earnings differences between younger and older cohorts with the same years of schooling. The earnings variations reflect three components: (i) the impact of changing selection into different years of schooling; (ii) return to experience; and (iii) the growth in the quality of education. Without a model, these three components cannot be identified simultaneously.

To assess the effect of the changing selection in schooling choice, assume that ability distribution stays constant across cohorts. If years of schooling vary only by ability within cohorts, the cohort-invariant ability distribution can be estimated by the schooling distribution of any single cohort. The impact of the changing selection on the cohort-variations in earnings is then measured by accounting for changes in empirical schooling distribution across cohorts.

Once the selection effect is controlled for, a structural restriction derived from the model is used to disentangle the remaining two components, assuming the same return to experience across cohorts. In the model, optimizing agents choose both time in school and educational expenditures so that their relative marginal product in increasing human capital equals their relative costs. Given the data on individual earnings and educational expenditures, foregone earnings due to delayed experience are the key element in the relative cost of time spent in school. If earnings rise with work experience very rapidly, increasing time in school is relatively more costly than raising educational expenditures. Thus, agents substitute expenditure for time in school until the relative marginal product of expenditure equals its low relative cost. According to the model, the relative marginal product of expenditure for the last year in school equals the expenditure elasticity of human capital. Thus, the low relative marginal product of expenditure represents a low value for the elasticity. This implies little increase in the quality of education, given the rise in school expenditures. By the same mechanism, very flat experience-earnings profiles suggest a substantial rise in education quality, given the same increase in educational spending. This model implication on how the return to experience relates to the rise in school quality provides an additional condition, which identifies the growth in quality of education from the observed earnings variations across cohorts.

The main finding is that U.S. labor quality increased by 0.4% per year between 1967 and 2000, with one-fifth of this explained by the growth in school quality. Given the increased school expenditures per pupil, their contribution to U.S. labor quality growth has been fairly modest. The total labor quality growth explains one-quarter of the growth in U.S. labor productivity for the same period. The estimated rise in labor quality reduces the growth rate of total factor productivity (TFP) measured as a residual. The contribution of growth in TFP to U.S. labor productivity growth is about a quarter, whereas the BLS estimates it to be 40% by ignoring the growth in the quality of education. The estimated impact of the rise in school expenditures on labor quality growth is larger among men, while the baseline estimate changes little with a sample of full-time, full-year (FTFY) workers. I also find that the growth in school quality explains only 10% of the increases in empirical returns to schooling and that a rising skill premium explains the rest.

This paper is related to two strands of literature. One branch includes papers that estimate the effects of various measures of school quality, including school expenditures on student achievement and labor market outcomes at the micro-level. Although the estimates vary depending on the data and method used, most papers did not find strong effects of measured school quality.1 My study differs from these studies in two ways: (i) it suggests an aggregate measure of labor quality growth due to increased school expenditures; and (ii) it focuses on cohort variations in the quality of education instead of cross-sectional or geographical variations. To this aim, the biggest challenge is to identify the growth in education quality from other earnings variations across cohorts such as return to experience and changing selection in schooling choice. This paper proposes a way of overcoming this difficulty using a schooling model and measures the average impact of increased school expenditures on growth in human capital for cohorts born from the early 20th century to the early 1980s. The estimated impact of school expenditures is modest in line with this micro-literature.

Another related strand of literature is on the role of human capital in economic growth and development. The most widely used method to measure country-level human capital stocks is to multiply the mean years of schooling of the population by the estimated Mincerian return to schooling.2 However, this method does not allow for differences in the quality of education across countries. To correct this, Bils and Klenow (2000) add teachers׳ human capital to the standard Mincer-type human capital specification, yet they ignore the role of expenditure in human capital production. Manuelli and Seshadri (2007) and Erosa et al. (2010) explicitly incorporate expenditure as well as time as inputs for human capital production to account for cross-country income differences. The contribution of human capital growth to U.S. real income growth implied by Manuelli and Seshadri (2007) is more than twice my estimate, whereas that suggested by Erosa et al. (2010) is only slightly greater than mine. One explanation is that Manuelli and Seshadri (2007) view that earnings growth with work experience is solely due to human capital investments, excluding the effects of learning-by-doing or technological progress. This framework tends to amplify the differences in human capital accumulated after leaving school across cohorts, overstating the role of human capital in explaining real income growth. In addition, both Manuelli and Seshadri (2007) and Erosa et al. (2010) assume a common wage per unit of labor regardless of education, whereas my study considers different skill prices by education; failing to do so overestimates the impact of rising school spending on labor quality growth. This paper also relates to Rangazas (2002), who examines the impact of the quantity and quality of schooling on U.S. labor productivity growth. A key difference is that my paper proposes a new way of estimating the expenditure elasticity of human capital, instead of taking it from micro-study estimates that vary by the data and method used. Moreover, I control for the rise in skill premium and unobserved heterogeneity correlated with schooling choice to remove upward bias in the estimated growth in U.S. labor quality.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the growth accounting framework this paper suggests and discusses the BLS׳s measure of labor quality growth. In Section 3, a schooling model with a Ben-Porath-type human capital production function is introduced. The identification scheme and the estimation procedure are described in Section 4, and the main findings are reported in Section 5. Section 6 concludes the paper.

Section snippets

Measuring labor quality growth

This study suggests that the traditional growth accounting framework should be extended by incorporating labor quality growth. Consider a production function in which economic output Y depends on m types of physical capital inputs k1, k2, …, km; n types of labor inputs h1l1, h2l2, …, hnln; and a time-specific factor t. Y=f(k1,,km,h1l1,,hnln,t)In this formula, lj is raw hours provided by type j workers and hj is its quality per hour.

Assuming a constant returns to scale technology, perfectly

The model

This paper develops a schooling model with a Ben-Porath-type human capital production function.5 Individuals born in period T choose the optimal level of schooling and goods investment associated with each year in school to maximize the present value of their net lifetime income:maxd(a),ssRerawT+a(s)H(s,a)da0serapT+ad(a)da+ξTh(s)s.t.H(s,a)=h(s)ϕ(as)forash(a)=γ0h(a)γ1d(a)γ2fora<s0<γ1,γ2<1andh(0)=1here r is the market interest rate; wt(s) is the wage

Identification and estimation

In this section, how to identify the growth in school quality from other sources of earnings variations across cohorts is addressed. The estimation procedure then follows.

Results

This section starts with a discussion of the estimates for the human capital production function. It then presents the main growth accounting results, followed by a sensitivity analysis.

Conclusion

Building upon Denison (1962), the BLS incorporates labor quality growth as a source of U.S. labor productivity growth. Although the BLS measure of labor quality growth adjusts for the increases in mean years of schooling of the workforce, it fails to capture any impact of the rise in school quality. Public school spending per pupil in the U.S. increased drastically during the 20th century. If this contributed to the quality of U.S. education, then the BLS approach underestimates labor quality

Acknowledgments

I am deeply indebted to Mark Bils for his generous support and encouragement. For their valuable comments and helpful discussions, I thank Mark Aguiar, Yongsung Chang, Jay H. Hong, Byoung Hoon Seok, and seminar participants at the University of Rochester, the State University of New York at Buffalo, the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Korea Development Institute, University of Western Ontario, Korea University, Far Eastern Meetings of the Econometric Society 2008, and Midwest Macro Meetings

References (18)

There are more references available in the full text version of this article.

Cited by (5)

  • Early childhood education and economic growth

    2019, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control
    Citation Excerpt :

    This article extends and improves the previous literature in several directions. First, we relate to the literature that studies human capital accumulation in a dynamic macroeconomic framework (Castro and Coen-Pirani, 2016; Kong et al., 2018; Lee and Wolpin, 2010; Rangazas, 2000; 2002; Restuccia and Vandenbroucke, 2013a; 2013b; You, 2014). None of these articles studies early childhood education.

View full text