Notes
Endogenous credit limits with small default costs

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2012.08.004Get rights and content

Abstract

We analyze an exchange economy of unsecured credit where borrowers have the option to declare bankruptcy in which case they are temporarily excluded from financial markets. Endogenous credit limits are imposed that are just tight enough to prevent default. Economies with temporary exclusion differ from their permanent exclusion counterparts in two important properties. If households are extremely patient, then the first-best allocation is an equilibrium in the latter economies but not necessarily in the former. In addition, temporary exclusion permits multiple stationary equilibria, with both complete and with incomplete consumption smoothing.

Introduction

The role of limited contract enforcement in dynamic general equilibrium has been explored extensively in key papers by Eaton and Gersovitz [11], Kehoe and Levine [14], Kocherlakota [17], and Kiyotaki and Moore [16], all of which seek to explain why individual consumption, aggregate output and asset prices fluctuate more than aggregate consumption, productivity or dividends. Limited commitment has been used to investigate anomalies in asset pricing (Alvarez and Jermann [1], [2], Azariadis and Kaas [6]), international business cycles (Kehoe and Perri [13]), economic growth (Marcet and Marimon [20]), consumption patterns and social security issues (Krueger and Perri [18], [19], Andolfatto and Gervais [3]). All these models describe environments in which a shortage of collateral rules out complete risk sharing or consumption smoothing. One institution that improves the distribution of consumption over households is unsecured credit backed by limiting defaultersʼ subsequent trading in asset markets. The literature typically assumes that an omnipotent credit authority or auctioneer excludes defaulting agents for the rest of their lives from any asset trade. Such a penalty is clearly the strongest possible punishment in the absence of collateral.

This paper explores the consequences of weaker punishment arrangements. For example, Bulow and Rogoff [8] and Hellwig and Lorenzoni [12] impose one-sided exclusion which permits defaulters to accumulate assets but banishes them permanently from all borrowing. This paper works out the consequences of temporary exclusion from both sides of asset markets. To this end, we consider a stochastic pure-exchange economy in which defaulters are readmitted to asset trading with positive probability. When the punishment period is over, bankrupt households regain full access to all markets. We maintain the common assumption in the literature of a complete market of state-contingent claims supported by default-deterring credit limits. We believe that temporary exclusion is an important feature since real-world bankruptcy procedures never come close to perpetual market exclusion.

Under permanent market exclusion, Alvarez and Jermann [1] prove two results: one, autarky is the unique (and constrained efficient) equilibrium if the autarkic interest rate exceeds the economyʼs growth rate. Two, when the autarky equilibrium is inefficient, there is a better equilibrium with improved risk sharing. Moreover, Kehoe and Levine [14, Proposition 2] establish a kind of “folk theorem”: this constrained efficient equilibrium is first best provided that the common discount factor is sufficiently large. This paper considers a particular equilibrium refinement, namely, the robustness to small explicit default costs. For our class of pure-exchange economies we find that permanent market exclusion gives rise to a unique robust equilibrium. In particular, autarky is not robust to this refinement, unless it is the unique equilibrium.

We show that economies with temporary exclusion differ from their permanent exclusion counterparts in two important ways. First, a higher discount factor does not necessarily help to implement the first best allocation. With temporary exclusion of defaulters and no matter how low the (positive) readmission probability is, the first-best allocation is not self-enforcing, even when agents are extremely patient, unless they are also sufficiently risk averse. Intuitively, very patient households care less about temporary exclusion penalties but are more interested in the expected value of consumption after they are readmitted to asset trade. Default raises both consumption risk during the punishment phase but also the expected value of consumption in the long run (i.e. after readmission to financial markets).

Second, temporary exclusion can give rise to the existence of multiple robust equilibria. In particular, we prove that autarky is always a robust equilibrium if the readmission probability is sufficiently high (i.e. punishment is sufficiently weak). Besides the robust autarky equilibrium, additional stationary equilibria can emerge; the first-best allocation may be one of them. To understand why multiple robust equilibria occur under temporary exclusion although they are impossible under permanent exclusion, we note that temporary exclusion introduces a dynamic complementarity between future and current asset prices. Consider the example of a defaulter who loses the ability to save in the default period but is readmitted to trade in all subsequent periods. Then an increase in future interest rates reduces the continuation value from default (because the agent forgoes asset trade in the default period) which relaxes credit constraints today. In turn, a higher volume of borrowing necessitates a higher current interest rate to clear the credit market today. This dynamic complementarity can trigger equilibrium multiplicity provided that the impact of future market prices on the value of default is sufficiently strong. Note that such a link is absent in economies with infinite market exclusion where default leads to permanent autarky whose payoff is independent of future prices. We present a more elaborate discussion of this argument in Section 4.

We are aware of only a few contributions dealing with temporary asset market exclusion of defaulting borrowers. Athreya [5] and Chatterjee et al. [9] develop quantitative equilibrium models with incomplete asset markets, characterizing optimal default behavior and equilibrium loan price schedules. In the sovereign default literature, temporary market exclusion of defaulting international borrowers is also a common assumption (Arellano [4], Cuadra, Sanchez and Sapriza [10]). However, these contributions neither discuss equilibrium multiplicity nor the role of discounting which are the focus of this paper.1 Azariadis and Lambertini [7] consider a deterministic overlapping-generations economy with three-period lived individuals, also demonstrating the existence of multiple equilibria. In their paper endogenous debt constraints are based on one-period exclusion by construction since individuals die in the period after default. Our paper shows that similar results can be obtained in stochastic economies with infinitely-lived agents.

The paper is organized as follows. After introducing the economic environment and equilibrium concepts in Section 2, we discuss first-best allocations and the role of discounting in Section 3. Section 4 considers equilibria with binding credit constraints and establishes our main result on equilibrium multiplicity and robustness.

Section snippets

States and agents

We consider a pure exchange economy in discrete time t=0,1, with a unit mass of consumers i[0,1] who face idiosyncratic income risk. There is a single non-durable consumption good in each period. Every consumerʼs endowment of this good follows a two-state Markov process between a high level y(H)=λ>1 and a low level y(L)<1. We define transition probabilities π(H|H)=πH, π(L|H)=1πH, π(L|L)=πL, π(H|L)=1πL, and we normalize mean income to one, which implies that y(L)=1(λ1)1πL1πH. We write sti

Implementing the first-best allocation

This section identifies conditions under which the symmetric first-best allocation where all agents consume the same, cHi=cLi=1, is an equilibrium with limited enforcement.3

Binding debt limits

We now consider stationary Markov equilibria with constrained borrowers. Binding debt limits are equivalent to incomplete consumption smoothing, that is, to x>1>cL(x). Security prices, as well as the credit constraint b(x), are stated in Lemma 1. With low-income agents being constrained in short-selling security aLH, the equilibrium definition entails that the agent must be exactly indifferent between honoring the debt aLH=b(x) and defaulting. An agent who stays solvent in a high-income period

Conclusions

We have studied how the sanctions against default on unsecured credit affect the allocation of consumption in a class of stochastic exchange economies with infinitely-lived agents and limited commitment. Strong sanctions, modeled as perpetual exclusion from both sides of all asset markets, are known to deliver “good” results as in Kehoe and Levine [14] and Alvarez and Jermann [1]. Among these is the generic existence of one or two steady states: a constrained efficient outcome, and an inferior

References (20)

There are more references available in the full text version of this article.

Cited by (18)

  • Optimal credit fluctuations

    2018, Review of Economic Dynamics
  • Introduction to economic theory of bubbles II

    2016, Journal of Mathematical Economics
  • Robust bubbles with mild penalties for default

    2016, Journal of Mathematical Economics
    Citation Excerpt :

    As it will be shown, these martingale components in debt limits can be substituted by fiat money (or by unbacked public debt), justifying the use of the term “bubble”. I document the existence of bubbles for some of the most common penalties for default encountered in the literature: a permanent interdiction to trade (IT) (Kehoe and Levine, 1993, 2001, or Alvarez and Jermann, 2000, 2001), a temporary interdiction to trade for a finite and deterministic number of periods (ITF) (Azariadis and Kaas, 2008), or an interdiction to trade for a random number of periods (ITR) (Azariadis and Kaas, 2013). Under penalty (IT), a defaulting agent is permanently excluded from the markets and consumes his endowment.

  • Uniqueness of competitive equilibrium with solvency constraints under gross-substitution

    2015, Journal of Mathematical Economics
    Citation Excerpt :

    In the literature on limited commitment, not-too-tight debt limits are endogenously determined by participation constraints. This introduces a potential non-monotonicity which might destroy the regularity delivered by gross-substitution and induce complicated dynamics at equilibrium (see, for instance, Azariadis and Kaas, 2013). However, under some conditions, the endogenous debt limits exhibit a form of dynamic complementarity: given prices, more permissive debt limits in the future induce more permissive debt limits in the present.

  • Dynamic Adverse Selection and Belief Update in Credit Markets

    2024, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
View all citing articles on Scopus

We are grateful to a referee and to an associate editor for helpful comments. Leo Kaas thanks the German Research Foundation (grant No. KA 1519/3) for financial support. The usual disclaimer applies.

View full text