Controlling Rhododendron ponticum in the British Isles: an economic analysis

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2003.12.009Get rights and content

Abstract

What resources should be committed to the control of invasive species? This study is based on a survey of nature conservation and forestry authorities, wildlife trusts and private landowners which investigated the extent of the ecological and economic impacts of the invasive non-native plant Rhododendron ponticum in the British Isles. There are data on 52,000 ha of land affected by R. ponticum, more than 30,000 ha of it in nature reserves. For nearly all nature reserves, displacement of native species and habitat changes were both reported. In 2001, respondents controlled 1275 ha of R. ponticum at a cost of £670,924. To test the optimality of this, we apply a model of social expenditure. The external costs of R. ponticum control are estimated from the probability that it will spread to contiguous sites and the damage done on invaded sites. These are then used to calculate the socially optimal level of expenditure on R. ponticum control, and the funding gap it identified by comparing the result with current levels of expenditure. The results suggest that a socially optimal level of control effort requires a significant increase in social funding for R. ponticum control, although the size of the increase varies between landholders.

Introduction

Increasing attention has been paid recently to the economic consequences of invasive species (US OTA, 1993, Perrings et al., 2000, Pimentel et al., 2000, Pimentel, 2002). The economic consequences of invasive species include damage costs, such as biodiversity loss or habitat change, plus the costs of control or eradication net of any possible benefits. Whereas damage costs are not directly calculable, the costs of control and eradication are. The costs of control are a measure of the effort committed to the eradication or reduction of an invasive species. Since individual landowners will increase control effort up to the point where marginal benefits and costs are equal, this can be seen as an indicator of the marginal private damage due to the invasive species. Depending on the species, the private benefits of control may not be a good measure of the social benefits. Benefits can be widely dispersed across the different stakeholders concerned, and aggregate costs can be difficult to estimate.

The spread of any invasive species depends on the control efforts of all those affected. The control costs faced by each person accordingly depend partly on conditions on the invaded site, and partly on conditions in neighbouring sites. Put another way, the private damage costs of harmful invasive species may be expected to be strictly less than the social damage costs.

In this paper, we are interested in the determinants of private expenditure on the control of a particular invasive species (Rhododendron ponticum), and in the options open to induce private landowners to undertake socially optimal level of control. To do this we investigate the extent of the problem of the invasive non-native plant R. ponticum in the British Isles, both from an ecological and economic perspective. We consider the species in its entire synanthropic area thus including a wide spectrum of different natural and socio-economic conditions. We use a survey of potentially affected groups to generate data on control costs, the reasons why people control R. ponticum, and what control options they consider. Surveys are a standard way of generating such data in the social sciences. They have also been used by biologists. Perrins et al., 1992, Kowarik and Schepker, 1998, Williamson, 1998 have used questionnaire surveys before to get results on the perception of non-native species in general and their control in a certain areas. The taxonomy in the paper follows Stace (1997).

R. ponticum was introduced into Britain as an ornamental garden plant about 1763 (Curtis, 1803). Its native area is in the region of the Black Sea (Turkey, Georgia, Bulgaria) with disjunct occurrences in Lebanon, Spain and Portugal. The plants occurring in the British Isles today originate from Spain mostly (Milne and Abbott, 2000). First reports on its self-sowing abilities in Britain date back to the year 1849 (Hooker, 1849). Seeding may be one reason for its success as an ornamental plant in gardens and parks as well as for the use in extensive plantings for game cover, especially pheasants, in woodlands, particularly in the 19th Century (Elliott, 1996). Where conditions favoured establishment, it subsequently spread from these sites. R. ponticum was also used almost exclusively as the stock for grafted rhododendrons (Royal Horticulture Society, 1951), but it is so vigorous that it constantly sends up suckers which, if not removed, gradually take all the sap from the plant, eventually causing the grafted variety to die off (Cox, 1998). It is not known how far occurrences of R. ponticum go back to plantings of these grafted rootstocks. Today R. ponticum is widespread over the whole British Isles occurring in 2238 out of 3844 grid cells of (10 km)2 (Preston et al., 2002).

Naturalisation has taken place in natural and near natural vegetation like acid oak woods, heaths and bogs. R. ponticum causes ecological modifications such as changes in the species composition, light reduction, prevention of regeneration of native shrubs and trees, thus endangering native species (e.g. Cross, 1975, Fuller and Boorman, 1977, Shaw, 1984, Thomson et al., 1993, Compton et al., 2002). However, forestry plantations, both conifer and broadleaf, are also invaded causing problems for forest management (Brown, 1953, Robinson, 1980, Tabbush and Williamson, 1987, Edwards et al., 2000). Consequently, the first experiments on best eradication techniques took place in 1949. They were carried out by the Forestry Commission (Brown, 1953, Miller, 1954) later followed by control measures in nature reserves and on private estates ([15], Gritten, 1987, Becker, 1988, Searle, 1999, Singleton and Rawlins, 1999).

Today R. ponticum is probably the major alien environmental weed in the British Isles (Williamson, 2002).

The economic problem investigated is the following. Since each landowner incurs direct costs from the presence of R. ponticum they will control the species up to the point where the private marginal benefits of control (the private marginal damage avoided) is equal to the private marginal costs of control. But control of R. ponticum in any one site also reduces the probability that it will spread in other sites. So the social marginal benefit of control (the social damage avoided) includes the damage avoided on contiguous sites. Since landowners in general have no incentive to increase control effort up to the point where their private control costs equal the social damage avoided, if landowners are left to choose the level of control they exercise, there will be too little control from the perspective of society.

To see the problem consider the following simple model. Let output on the ith of n contiguous sites, Qi, depend on a vector of m inputs, Xi, and on the extent of R. ponticum on that site, Ri. Further, let the extent of R. ponticum on the ith site depend on the level of control undertaken in all sites, j=1nEj.

That isQi=Qix1i…xmi,Rij=1nEj

We can identify two problems: a private problem and a social problem.

The private decision problem takes the form:MaxXi,EiΠi=pQi−c(Xi,Ei)subject to Eq. (1), where

    Πi

    profit on the ith site

    p

    the price of output

    ci

    c(Xi,Ei), costs on the ith site.

The first order necessary conditions for the solution of this problem include the following:

pQXii−cXii=0pQRiiREii−cEii=0

implying that private landowners will equate the private marginal benefits and costs of their control effort. The social decision problem takes the formMaxSΠ=in[pQi−c(Xi,Ei(S))]subject to Eq. (1) and the way in which private effort depends on the policy instruments, S. The first order necessary condition for the solution of this problem includes the following:

pQRiiREiiESi+j≠inpQRjjREijESi−cEiiESi=0,∀i

In which j≠inpQRjjREij is the impact of control on the ith site on the value of output on all other contiguous sites. In the private decision problem the decision-maker has no incentive to take into account the effects of their actions on others. Solution of the social decision problem requires that they do. In the absence of intervention, there will be too little control. The implication of this is that it would be socially desirable to induce people, through choice of the policy instruments, S, to undertake the socially optimal level of control.

We have two problems to solve. The first is the estimation of the marginal external damage costs of R. ponticum in any one site—i.e. the value of the term j≠inpQRjjREij. The second is the specification and estimation of a control effort function in order to calculate the optimal value of S. We take the general form of such a control effort function to be Ei=Ei(Zi,S) where Z is a vector of control inputs.

In other words we wish to calculate (a) how far current control efforts may fall short of the socially optimal control effort, and (b) what policy, S, would induce the socially optimal level of control.

Section snippets

Description of the survey

Data were obtained by designing and administering a questionnaire to landowners and land managers. The questionnaire elicited information on three main topics: (a) general information about R. ponticum and its presence on sites, (b) the control regime, and (c) the costs (see Appendix A). Addressees were asked to give estimates if they did not know the exact numbers requested. The questions about the control regime and control costs relate to 2001. Figures for 2000 were also accepted if control

Model of the control effort

The next step is to identify the best mechanism for achieving the optimal level of control. To do this we specify a control effort function. This relates control effort to (a) the scale of the current problem, (b) the private control costs, (c) external funding of control inputs, (d) external labour support (volunteer labour). The area controlled in the reference year is taken to represent the control effort. We assume a Cobb-Douglas control effort function, implying an estimated function of

Discussion

R. ponticum has negative effects on nature conservation and forestry in the British Isles—a fact which respondents to the survey are highly aware of. R. ponticum imposes high costs on all groups, and many commit significant resources to control and restore land invaded by R. ponticum. Nevertheless, in an analysis designed to test the level of control effort relative to the social optimum, we find that this level of effort falls significantly short of what is needed. To be socially optimal,

Conclusion

The continued spread of R. ponticum imposes high costs in terms of habitat loss, production losses in forestry and agriculture in the British Isles. Taking these costs into account we find that current control levels are below the socially optimal level. This implies that there should be a significant increase in funding for R. ponticum control by central or local government, although the size of the increase varies between landscapes. We also find that a subsidy on the control costs would be

Acknowledgements

We are very grateful to all participants of the inquiry, too many to name here. We thank particularly John Everitt (Wildlife Trusts UK), John Harvey (National Trust), Scottish Natural Heritage, National Trust for Scotland, Colin Edwards (Forestry Commission), John Cross (Duchas), the Country Land and Business Association and the Scottish Landowner Federation who helped to improve and distribute the questionnaire. Katharina Dehnen-Schmutz had been supported by a fellowship of the Deutsche

References (39)

  • Cross, J.R., 2002. The invasion and control of Rhododendron ponticum L. in native Irish vegetation. In: Kowarik, I.,...
  • W. Curtis

    Rhododendron ponticum

    Botanical Magazine

    (1803)
  • C. Edwards et al.

    Stem treatment to control Rhododendron ponticum under woodland canopies

    Aspects of Applied Biology

    (2000)
  • B. Elliott

    Rhododendrons in British gardens: a short history

  • R.H. Gritten

    The spread of Rhododendron ponticum-a national problem

  • J.D. Hooker

    The Rhododendrons of the Sikkim-Himalaya

    (1849)
  • W.I. Jones

    A rhododendron eradication trial

    (1974)
  • M.J. Keeling et al.

    Dynamics of the 2001 UK foot and mouth epidemic:stochastic dispersal in a heterogeneous landscape

    Science

    (2001)
  • K.J. Kirby et al.

    The Ancient Woodland Inventory in England and its Uses

  • Cited by (53)

    • Larger hardwood trees benefit from removing Rhododendron maximum following Tsuga canadensis mortality

      2022, Forest Ecology and Management
      Citation Excerpt :

      Removal of the understory vegetation layer is one of the strategies that can be applied to restore forest vegetation structure and composition (Stanturf et al., 2014). Studies have attempted the removal of R. maximum in the eastern United States (Hooper, 1969; Romancier, 1971; Harrell, 2006), or similar species in Europe (Rhododendron ponticum, see Dehnen-Schmutz et al. (2004); Eşen and Zedaker (2004); Maclean et al. (2018b; 2018a)). However, only a few studies have examined the effects of removing R. maximum on ecosystem processes (Elliott and Miniat, 2018; Osburn, 2018).

    • Tidying up the cluttered understorey: Foraging strategy mediates bat activity responses to invasive rhododendron

      2020, Forest Ecology and Management
      Citation Excerpt :

      Due to its ability to out-compete native plant species, suppress tree and shrub regeneration, and to act as a potential host for the fungal pathogens Phytophthora ramorum and Phytophthora kernoviae, rhododendron is being cleared using methods such as mechanical flailing, cutting and burning, and treatment with herbicides (Jackson, 2008; Parrott and MacKenzie, 2013). These removal projects are very time consuming and expensive; depending on site characteritics and the degree of infestation, they may take up to ten years (Edwards, 2006) and cost up to £10,000 per hectare in extreme cases (Dehnen-Schmutz et al., 2004; Parrott and MacKenzie, 2013). Due to its toxicity, rhododendron is not browsed by native mammals and grazing of young plants has little lasting effect (Cross, 1975).

    • Bioeconomic model for optimal control of the invasive weed Zea mays subspp. (teosinte) in Spain

      2018, Agricultural Systems
      Citation Excerpt :

      The literature on invasive species management incorporating estimations of economic damages is relatively abundant since the 1990s in the United States, South Africa, Australia and New Zealand (see Born et al., 2005 and Pimentel et al., 2005 for a review of diverse species). Remarkably, however, with the exception of a few studies addressing the management of invasive species in natural ecosystems in Germany (Reinhardt et al., 2003; Nehring, 2005) and in the UK (Dehnen-Schmutz et al., 2004), research focusing on Europe is scarce. Even more surprising, little work has dealt with the impacts of invasive weeds in agroecosystems.

    • Integrating demographic data and a mechanistic dispersal model to predict invasion spread of Rhododendron ponticum in different habitats

      2011, Ecological Informatics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Therefore it may be in deciduous woodlands, particularly those with relatively low canopy cover, where the most problematic infestations of R. ponticum are likely to occur. Following a survey of landowners and managers, Dehnen-Schmutz et al. (2004) concluded that R. ponticum presence and invasion is of most concern to the forestry industry as woodland is the habitat most affected. However, there is little detail given about any perceived differences in the impact of R. ponticum on the different types of woodland habitats.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text