Outsourcing strategy and production disruption of supply chain with demand and capacity allocation uncertainties

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2015.09.028Get rights and content

Abstract

This paper develops supply chain game models with multiple uncertainties, and studies the impact of channel power on the efficiency of supply chain. Besides the regular production run, the manufacturer may choose the outsourcing mode due to his production disruption risk and uncertainty of capacity allocation. We find that the manufacturer has no incentive to outsource when both the disruption risk is low enough and his production capacity is large enough. When the disruption risk is sufficiently high, the manufacturer will fully outsource production regardless of the production capacity. There is a zone of order-difference outsourcing where the manufacturer just outsources the part in excess of the certain threshold value. Under the retailer-Stackelberg (RS) game, the manufacturer׳s order-difference outsourcing strategy can induce the retailer to order more items. Unlike RS, the retailer in the manufacturer-Stackelberg (MS) game always orders a quantity equal to that in the classic newsvendor model. Meanwhile, we find that the channel power does not affect the player’s decision except in the zone of order-difference outsourcing. Compared with MS, the dominant retailer can better deal with the uncertainties and make better use of demand information. From the channel׳s perspective, the two players have the different attitudes towards the risks. The dominant manufacturer prefers to forcibly offload production risks to his partner, while the dominant retailer in RS actively takes the partner׳s risks.

Introduction

Owing to the complexity and dynamicity of supply chain environment, the disruption in supply networks is identified as one of the important supply chain risks. Supply disruptions may be caused by natural or man-made disasters such as equipment breakdowns, labor strikes, traffic interruptions, earthquakes, floods, and hurricanes. The recent research in this field focuses on the study of inventory systems in the presence of supply disruptions. Supply disruptions can lead to excessive down time of production resources, significant delay in customer delivery, financial loss, and eventually a loss in the market value of firm (Burke et al., 2007). As the risk of supply disruption increases, it is crucial for firms to learn how to anticipate and manage it. A firm׳s performance may drop sharply once the full impact of the disruption hits (Sheffi and Rice, 2005, Matsuo, 2015). Examples of supply chain vulnerabilities are widespread:

Example 1. According to a study performed by Computer Sciences Corporation in 2003, 43% of 142 companies, ranging from consumer goods to health care, reported that their supply chains were vulnerable to disruptions, and 55% of these companies had no documented contingency plans (Poirier and Quinn, 2003). Additionally, according to another survey performed by CFO Research Services, 38% of 247 companies acknowledged that they had too much unmanaged supply chain disruption risk (Eskew, 2004).

Example 2. A representative example is the March 2000 fire at the Philips microchip plant in Albuquerque, New Mexico. Nokia changed product configurations and took advantage of outsourcing strategy in the nick of time to meet customer demand during a supply disruption (Latour, 2001).

Example 3. To handle both the uncertain demand fluctuation and supply disruption, HP used the Singapore plant for the base volume production and outsourced the remaining portion of their production to a contract manufacturer in Malaysia. A flexible supply base not only enables a firm to handle the uncertain demand risk, but also it can be used to maintain continuous supply of materials when supply disruption occurs (Billington and Johnson, 2002).

The potential economic impact of a disruption is a critical issue for supply chain management, while it increases the awareness of significant risks posed by supply failures which highlights the need for effective disruption management. Therefore, supply disruption has made companies aware of the need for active disruption management. Risk management provides alternative ways to hedge against disruption risks. One of the most common policies for risk mitigation is flexible multiple-sourcing (Chen et al., 2001). The multiple-sourcing supply becomes a common business practice to lessen the risk of supply disruption, especially in the high-technology industries. For example, many product categories, from car batteries to printer cartridges and computers, can be supplied from the alternative outsourcing if the supply disruptions occur. Therefore, our first objective is to investigate the manufacturer’s outsourcing strategy and the retailer׳s order strategy when facing the supply disruption.

Our paper analyzes how uncertainty risks affect both sides of the manufacturer–retailer relationship under the two channel leadership structures. The channel leadership structure represents relative channel power. One is manufacturer-Stackelberg (MS) structure, and the other is retailer-Stackelberg (RS) structure. We explore both structures and show that the double marginalization effect results in a lower outsourcing quantity, which leads to supply insufficiency for the buyer. The overwhelming majority of studies in game-theoretic supply chains examine MS structures. However, in the past decades many powerful retailers have appeared around the world. For a dominant retailer such as Wal-Mart, there are many manufacturers producing similar types of products and most are willing to make concessions and vigorous cooperation because they are keen to sell their products through it. Thus, a dominant retailer has many choices and, consequently, owns the power to dictate prices of products. Therefore, the second objective of our paper is to investigate how the channel power affects the behavior of players as well as the channel profit.

The third objective of the paper is to investigate how to coordinate each channel structure with multiple uncertainties, including the outside demand uncertainty, and the inside allocation uncertainty and disruption risk. The objective is to formally analyze how the dominant player deals with the uncertain risks to avoid the double marginalization effect and establish channel competitive advantage. A coordinated supply chain performs better than the uncoordinated one. However, each player in the supply chain is primarily concerned with optimizing his own objective, which decreases channel profit and lowers channel competitive advantage. It has been proven in the literature that some effective contracts can be designed to access channel coordination, which leads to an improved channel profit. Therefore, from the channel׳s perspective, we will investigate how the uncertainties from both supply side and demand side affect the behavior of players and study how the dominant player deals with the uncertainties.

To be specific, we consider the supply chain consisting of one manufacturer and one retailer, where the manufacturer supplies product to his partner with a random capacity allocation and possible production disruption risk, and the retailer faces the uncertain market demand. In addition to a regular production run, the manufacturer may choose the outsourcing mode. We find that there is a zone of order-difference outsourcing where the manufacturer partly resorts to outsourcing. Meanwhile, the manufacturer׳s order-difference outsourcing strategy can induce the retailer to order more items. Compared with MS, RS can effectively compensate the manufacturer for the risk exposure associated with demand uncertainty, which results in the higher level of outsourcing quantity for the manufacturer. From the channel׳s perspective, we design the all-accepted punishment contract for each structure to avoid the double marginalization effect. In our unpredictable setting, the mechanism needs both players to collaborate fully in order to deal with production and demand uncertainties caused by channel decentralization. ‘All-accepted’ in the contract is expected to extend fullest cooperation between both players. Our main results also provide several insights regarding how the dominant player could use contracting and outsourcing to manage procurement decisions when facing demand uncertainty and supply disruption.

Section snippets

Literature review

Supply disruption is defined as the sudden stop of supply. That is, when unexpected events occur, the main source becomes unavailable. Supply disruption is an infrequent risk but has a large impact on the channel (Kleindorfer and Saad, 2005, Ellisa et al., 2010, Schmitt et al., 2010), because it can cut off the cash flow and stop the operation of the entire supply chain. Since the financial losses caused by supply disruptions may be huge, the problem of how to manage and control the potential

The Setting

We consider a supply chain consisting of one manufacturer and one retailer. The retailer faces a random demand for a finished product that he orders from the manufacturer. Regular production capacity of the manufacturer is denoted by Y. Since a supply chain usually is embedded into a complex supply network, the manufacturer may not have just one but several distributors. That is, the regular capacity is shared by all the customers whose orders arrive randomly and independently, the proportion

RS game

We now model the relationship between the manufacturer and the retailer as a sequential non-cooperative game with the retailer as the leader and the manufacturer as the follower. The solution of this game is called RS equilibrium. The simplest contract, i.e., the price-only contract, can be used as an inferiority benchmark for evaluating the performance of other contract formats. The corresponding steps of the game are presented as follows: (i) The retailer determines the order quantity. (ii)

The manufacturer-Stackelberg (MS) supply chain

In this section, we investigate how the dominant manufacturer replenishes from the outsourcing supplier and deals with his own risks, and study the impacts of both demand uncertainty and supply risks on the manufacturer. Meanwhile, the coordination mechanism for MS channel is also designed.

Numerical experiments

The main objective of our numerical experiments is to evaluate the impact of both outsourcing cost and disruption risk on the optimal performances of channel members, outsourcing level and its value. In this section, we describe the results for the basic case and some interesting sensitivity analysis with respect to the relevant parameters. The numerical comparisons illustrate how the channel leadership affects the decisions and the expected profits. Without loss of generality, we assume that

Discussions and conclusions

Although sourcing from a single supplier will enable a firm to reduce cost (lower supply management cost, lower unit cost due to quantity discount, etc.), it could create problems for managing inherent supply disruptions or demand fluctuations. Nokia׳s success and HP׳s operating model give effective management for these risks by using the outsourcing decision. In this paper, we consider both the outsourcing decision and coordination mechanisms for two Stackelberg-game structures with multiple

Acknowledgments

The authors thank an associate editor and anonymous referees for their numerous constructive comments and encouragement that have improved our paper greatly. The work was partly supported by (i) the National Natural Science Foundation of China (71571100, 71371093 and 71201083); (ii) China National Funds for Distinguished Young Scientists (71425001); (iii) Jiangsu Province Science Foundation for Youths (BK2012379); and (iv) the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (NS2015076).

References (63)

  • O. Kaya

    Incentive and production decisions for remanufacturing operations

    Eur. J. Oper. Res.

    (2010)
  • X. Li et al.

    Double marginalization and coordination in the supply chain with uncertain supply

    Eur. J. Oper. Res.

    (2013)
  • Z. Liu et al.

    Supply chain outsourcing under exchange rate risk and competition

    Omega

    (2011)
  • H. Matsuo

    Implications of the Tohoku earthquake for Toyota׳s coordination mechanism: supply chain disruption of automotive semiconductors

    Int. J. Prod. Econ.

    (2015)
  • K. Pan et al.

    Two-period pricing and ordering policy for the dominant retailer in a two-echelon supply chain with demand uncertainty

    Omega

    (2009)
  • X. Qi et al.

    Supply chain coordination with demand disruptions

    Omega

    (2004)
  • S. Saha

    Supply chain coordination through rebate induced contracts

    Transp. Res. Part E: Logist. Transp. Rev.

    (2013)
  • A.J. Schmitt et al.

    Inventory systems with stochastic demand and supply: properties and approximations

    Eur. J. Oper. Res.

    (2010)
  • S. Sinha et al.

    Supply-chain coordination model with insufficient production capacity and option for outsourcing

    Math. Comput. Model.

    (2007)
  • A.A. Tsay

    Risk sensitivity in distribution channel partnerships: implications for manufacturer return policies

    J. Retail.

    (2002)
  • S.M. Wagner et al.

    Supplier switching decisions

    Eur. J. Oper. Res.

    (2007)
  • J.C. Wang et al.

    Practical and effective contracts for the dominant retailer of a newsvendor product with price-sensitive demand

    Int. J. Prod. Econ.

    (2012)
  • M. Weidenbaum

    Outsourcing: pros and cons

    Bus. Horiz.

    (2005)
  • T.J. Xiao et al.

    Price competition, cost and demand disruptions and coordination of a supply chain with one manufacturer and two competing retailers

    Omega

    (2008)
  • H.S. Yu et al.

    Single or dual sourcing: decision-making in the presence of supply chain disruption risks

    Omega

    (2009)
  • W.G. Zhang et al.

    Coordination of supply chain with a revenue-sharing contract under demand disruptions when retailers compete

    Int. J. Prod. Econ.

    (2012)
  • K. Zimmer

    Supply chain coordination with uncertain just-in-time delivery

    Int. J. Prod. Econ.

    (2002)
  • K.S. Anand et al.

    Strategic information management under leakage in a supply chain

    Manag. Sci.

    (2009)
  • F. Bernstein et al.

    Pricing and replenishment strategies in a distribution system with competing retailers

    Oper. Res.

    (2003)
  • C. Billington et al.

    A real options perspective on supply chain management in high technology

    J. Appl. Corp. Financ.

    (2002)
  • G.P. Cachon et al.

    Supply chain coordination with revenue sharing contracts: strengths and limitations

    Manag. Sci.

    (2005)
  • Cited by (66)

    • Risk-averse outsourcing strategy in the presence of demand and supply uncertainties

      2021, Computers and Industrial Engineering
      Citation Excerpt :

      Furthermore, in the risk-averse model, the sensitivity of the optimal outsourcing strategies with respect to the relevant parameters is investigated. Please note that all our computational experiments are based on the data adopted and adjusted from Chen and Xiao (2015a). All examples are solved using the Matlab R2016a software on HP desktop with the Intel Core i5 processor running at 2.3 GHz and 8 GB of RAM.

    • Collection disruption management and channel coordination in a socially concerned closed-loop supply chain: A game theory approach

      2020, Journal of Cleaner Production
      Citation Excerpt :

      Green R&D efforts influence the customer’s tendency to buy the manufacturer’s products and thus influence the retailers’ demand in the investigated market (from a theoretical viewpoint, such impacts of these efforts are also addressed by the previous literature such as Levin and Reiss (1989)). Due to such interrelations between the members’ decisions, it is of high importance to implement a practical coordination mechanism to deal with CLSC challenges and manage the interactions between the members (Chen and Xiao, 2015). This study analytically explores the role of coordination models in enhancing the performance of such systems dealing with competition in both forward and reverse channels and facing disruptions.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text