Elsevier

European Economic Review

Volume 54, Issue 2, February 2010, Pages 294-316
European Economic Review

Job search and academic achievement

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2009.07.001Get rights and content

Abstract

The paper develops a structural model for the labor market behavior of students entering the labor market. We explicitly model the trade-off between devoting effort to studying and to job search. Furthermore, we allow for on-the-job search. The model is estimated using a unique data set of individuals who completed undergraduate education in the Netherlands between 1995 and 2001. Our estimation results show that labor market returns of high grades are low. Wage increases between jobs are explained by labor market friction rather than returns of early work experience. Our results indicate that a 1 percentage point decrease in the unemployment rate increases wage offers on average by 3 percent, but that the amount of job search effort is not very sensitive to business cycle fluctuations. Policy simulations show that study effort and hence academic achievement are much more sensitive to financial incentives than job search effort and labor market outcomes.

Introduction

In the final stage of their academic studies, students not only study hard to improve academically, but also start looking for work. This paper focuses on the trade-off between studying and job search. We develop a job-search model describing labor market behavior of individuals around the moment at which they complete their education. The model allows us to investigate the transition from college to the labor market and the returns of better academic performance. Moreover, we exploit the relatively long observation period to consider the importance of business-cycle fluctuations for the labor market prospects of students.

In the empirical analysis we use a discrete-time job-search model with endogenous job-search and study effort. Whereas the returns of job search while studying are that individuals start their first job earlier, the returns of study effort take the form of better grades, which may have long-lasting positive returns on the labor market. Academic achievement is thus endogenous and depends not only on study effort but also on ability. Explicitly modeling job search prior to graduation provides a natural model for individuals who anticipate the moment of graduation and have not been unemployed between leaving school and starting work. We also allow for on-the-job search, since quite a number of individuals switches jobs within the first few years after leaving college (see Topel and Ward, 1992). Wages in the first job are thus not a proper indicator for the present value of life-time earnings (e.g. Eckstein and Wolpin, 1995). We do not require that the structural parameters describing the job search environment to be similar for individuals looking for their first job and for employed workers.

A structural model has several advantages when analyzing the labor market behavior of students. The fact that labor market transitions, wages and academic achievement are jointly determined, makes it possible to study the interdependency between these variables. Since we explicitly model study effort and job-search effort, we can use the model to investigate behavioral responses to policy interventions. In particular, we simulate the effects of reducing unemployment compensation for recent graduates and the effects of providing financial rewards for good academic performance.

Our model builds further on Wolpin (1987) and Ferrall (1997). Wolpin (1987) stipulates that all individuals start searching the same fixed period before graduation and that in each period they devote the same amount of effort to job search. Ferrall (1997) assumes that at the moment of graduation all individuals have received exactly two job offers, and are employed if the wage associated with the best job offer exceeds the individual's reservation wage. In our model job-search effort before graduation is endogenous—and thereby also the number of job offers collected before graduation.1 Other structural empirical analyses do not explicitly model the job-search process before graduation, which may cause selection bias. Bowlus et al. (2001) ignore search spells in which individuals start working immediately upon leaving school. Gras and Lindeboom (1994) adopt a similar strategy, but correct for potential selection among those who failed to find a job before graduation.

The empirical analyses in this paper use data from an annual survey of young workers who recently finished undergraduate education at Dutch universities. The data describe cohorts of individuals who graduated in economics, business, Dutch law or psychology between 1995 and 2001. Since labor market conditions for these individuals differ, we estimate our model separately for different studies. Our intention is not to estimate returns to education or to compare returns of the different studies. The data are described in a period in which the Dutch economy experienced a period of relatively fast growth until the end of the 1990s and a slowdown after 2000. We allow the structural parameters to depend on business-cycle indicators.

Our estimation results show that, conditional on graduating, the labor market returns to good academic performance are very low. This also explains the finding that study effort among college students in the Netherlands is low (e.g. Leuven et al., 2009). Low study effort is well recognized in the Dutch public debate, where students are often criticized for a lack of ambition to perform well in college. The very low labor market returns to good academic performance contradict most research on the transition from school to work coming from the US. However, Colonna (2007) finds that also in Italy the college premium is much lower than that in the US. Colonna (2007) and Krueger and Mueller (2008) show that there may be substantial differences between the US and European labor markets.

Because young workers lack relevant work experience, labor market outcomes of young workers are more sensitive to business-cycle fluctuations than are the labor market outcomes of older workers. Our empirical results show strong effects of macroeconomic conditions on labor market prospects of students. In particular, a 1 percentage-point decrease in the unemployment rate increases wage offers by around 3 percent. We find that the optimal job-search effort does not respond much to business-cycle fluctuations. This seems to contradict Shimer (2004), who argues that even though the returns of job search are lower during recessions, job-search effort can be increasing during recessions.

Between jobs, wages increase by about 16–19 percent. However, our models find evidence for substantial returns to early work experience. This implies that these wage increases are driven by labor market friction. This coincides with Topel and Ward (1992), who argue that young workers are searching for good matches and that the behavior of young workers is largely consistent with job search theory. Also Christensen et al. (2005) argue that the effect of tenure on wages is small in the wage growth of individuals.

Our estimated model will be used to perform two policy experiments. As of July 2009, individuals under the age 27 will no longer be entitled to collecting welfare benefits when unemployed. Since almost all individuals finish undergraduate education before that age, this policy change affects almost all individuals in our data set. Model simulations show only very modest effects on labor market outcomes. Reservation wages are already so low that most individuals accept all job offers. However, most students substitute study effort into job-search effort. Whereas grades drop dramatically, there is only a very modest increase in employment rates upon graduation. Our second policy experiment is to provide a financial reward to students who graduate with high grades. Simulations show that such a reward substantially increases study effort and academic performance. But because returns to high grades are low, labor market outcomes do not improve. A combination of both policies improves grades but leaves labor market outcomes almost unaffected. It should be noted that the amount paid to reward students with high grades is much lower than average welfare benefit payments.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides institutional background on the Dutch educational system and business cycle variation during the observation period. Section 3 presents the structural model and describes the estimation of our structural model. The data are discussed in Section 4. Section 5 presents results of reduced-form analyses to investigate the validity of the structural model. Section 6 presents the estimation results of the structural model. Section 7 concludes.

Section snippets

The Dutch educational system

Dutch universities are public, and tuition is low. Tuition is set by the government and does not vary by field of study or by university attended. Annual tuition fees for full-time students (under the age of 30) increased from around 800 euro in the early 1990s to around 1250 euro at the end of the 1990s. Undergraduate students are entitled to financial aid. The grant depends on parental income and whether or not students live with their parents (see Leuven et al., 2009, for a more extensive

The model

Our model is a discrete-time job-search model with endogenous search effort and on-the-job search, which we use to describe the transition from college to work. Burdett (1978) first derived a job-search model that allowed for on-the-job search, and Mortensen (1977) explicitly modeled search effort as an individual decision variable. Following Eckstein and Wolpin (1999), we assume that students nearing graduation face a trade-off between studying and job search. Study effort increases grades;

Data

Our data are from a survey of individuals who completed undergraduate education in the Netherlands.8 The survey is a written questionnaire that contains questions on education, job-search behavior, work history and personal characteristics. Each year (in January or

Reduced-form analyses

This section tests some predictions of the theoretical model by performing reduced-form analyses.

In our theoretical model we imposed the condition the wage-offer distribution before and after graduation had to be the same. Prior to graduation, students could collect multiple job offers and choose the best job offer at graduation. After graduation, individuals had to decide immediately whether or not to accept a job offer. Our theoretical model thus predicts expected wages in the first job to be

Parameter estimates

This section discusses the estimation results of the structural model. Since we will not explicitly compare the returns of the different studies, we will therefore (conditional on observed covariates) treat the choice of study as exogenous.

Table 6 provides the parameter estimates. The probability of graduating from college with high grades depends on both study effort and ability (measured by high school grades and age). Age is used as an ability measure to distinguish between students who

Conclusion

This paper developed a model that describes the labor market behavior of individuals around the time of graduation. Shortly before graduation individuals divide their effort between studying and job search. Study effort generates higher grades, while search effort increases the probability that an individual starts working immediately after graduation. Furthermore, our model allows for on-the-job search. We estimate our model in four samples of university graduates who are finishing an

Acknowledgments

We thank Peter Berkhout for making the data available and Kenneth Carling, Zvi Eckstein, Denis Fougère, Bertil Holmlund, Gregory Jolivet, Robert Shimer, Gerard van den Berg, three anonymous referees and participants at the 2004 CEPR conference on the “dynamic approach to Europe's unemployment problem” in Bristol and seminars at CREST-Paris, IFAU-Uppsala, SOFI-Stockholm, University of Zurich, RWI-Essen and IZA-Bonn for useful comments.

References (22)

  • C.J. Flinn et al.

    New methods for analyzing structural models of labor force dynamics

    Journal of Econometrics

    (1982)
  • H.G. Bloemen

    Job search, search intensity and labour market transitions: an empirical analysis

    Journal of Human Resources

    (2005)
  • A.J. Bowlus et al.

    Equilibrium search models and the transition from school to work

    International Economic Review

    (2001)
  • K. Burdett

    A theory of employee job search and quit rates

    American Economic Review

    (1978)
  • B.J. Christensen et al.

    On-the-job search and the wage distribution

    Journal of Labor Economics

    (2005)
  • Colonna, F., 2007. Labor market and schooling choice: Italy vs US. Working Paper, University of...
  • Z. Eckstein et al.

    Duration to first job and the returns to schooling: estimates from a search-matching model

    Review of Economic Studies

    (1995)
  • Z. Eckstein et al.

    Why youths drop out of high school: the impact of preferences, opportunities, and abilities

    Econometrica

    (1999)
  • C. Ferrall

    Unemployment insurance eligibility and the school-to-work transition in Canada and the United States

    Journal of Business and Economic Statistics

    (1997)
  • Fougère, D., Pradel, J., Roger, M., 2009. Does job-search assistance affect search effort and outcomes? A...
  • Gras, A., Lindeboom, M., 1994. The search process of law graduates in the Netherlands. Working Paper, Tinbergen...
  • Cited by (23)

    • Young, gifted and lazy? The role of ability and labor market prospects in student effort decisions

      2019, Economics of Education Review
      Citation Excerpt :

      Our evidence thus conforms to the conclusions of other researchers, such as Aina et al. (2011), who consider weak job prospects as an explanation for long study durations at Italian universities. In a similar fashion, van der Klaauw and van Vuuren (2010) argue that low labor market returns to academic performance explain the phenomenon of lacking ambition among Dutch students. It appears that we can provide empirical support for the important role of the labor market in student behavior for another country.23

    • Risk aversion and job mobility

      2019, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization
      Citation Excerpt :

      Although the LISS data does not contain information about acceptance or rejection of job offers, there is information available about job search activities of the respondents. In the previous literature, job search effort has been measured by the time spent on search activities (Krueger and Mueller, 2010), the number of applications in the past month(s) (van der Klaauw and van Vuuren, 2010), the number of job search channels (Manning, 2009) or a combination of some of these indicators (Bloemen, 2005; van Huizen and Alessie, 2015). Here we use three indicators of on-the-job search intensity that are available in the LISS: whether the worker applied for another job in the past two months; the number of applications in the past two months; and the number of job search channels the worker has used in the past two months.

    • Bad start, bad match? The early career effects of graduating in a recession for vocational and academic graduates

      2018, Labour Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Through job shopping, young workers search for a good match and they experience wage gains. Indeed, wage gains in early careers are for a substantial part explained by labor market frictions (van der Klaauw and van Vuuren, 2010; Topel and Ward, 1992). When graduates enter the labor market in a recession, there are fewer vacancies.

    • Time preferences and career investments

      2015, Labour Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      In the literature on (on-the-) job search behaviour, search intensity has been measured in a variety of ways. We use the following indicators to capture on-the-job search intensity: (1) search attitude: this variable equals 0 if the worker is not searching for a job, 1 if he is considering looking for another job and 2 if he reports to be seriously searching for another job (e.g., Bloemen, 2005); (2) a dummy indicating whether the worker has applied for a job in the past 2 months; (3) the number of job applications made by the worker during the last 2 months (e.g., Van der Klaauw and van Vuuren, 2010); (4) the number of job search channels used by the worker in the last 2 months (e.g., DellaVigna and Paserman, 2005).9 The latter may be interesting as previous empirical findings indicate that the number of search methods is positively related to the time spent searching per day (Krueger and Mueller, 2008).

    • Pure ethnic gaps in educational attainment and school to work transitions: When do they arise?

      2013, Economics of Education Review
      Citation Excerpt :

      The table indicates furthermore that immigrants have on average twice as many siblings as natives do and that the immigrant sample contains slightly more girls than that of the natives. The impact of the latter two variables on educational achievement and labor market outcomes is, however, not clearly established (Cameron & Heckman, 2001; Pozzoli, 2009; Ryan, 2001; van der Klaauw & Vuuren, 2010). In the literature one sometimes also controls in addition for family income, neighborhood characteristics, indicators of regional labor market conditions, the regional level of tuition fees and grants for college enrolment.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text