O.R. Applications
Cycles of violence: A dynamic control analysis

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2006.05.027Get rights and content

Abstract

We introduce and analyze a simple model of cycles of violence in which oscillations are generated when surges in lethal violence shrink the pool of active violent offenders. Models with such endogenously induced variation may help explain why historically observed trends in violence are generally not well correlated with exogenous forcing functions, such as changes in the state of the economy. The analysis includes finding the optimal dynamic trajectory of incarceration and violence prevention interventions. Those trajectories yield some surprising results, including situations in which myopic decision makers will invest more in prevention than will far-sighted decision makers.

Introduction

Rates of crime and violence can vary substantially over time, but the variations are not always well-correlated with indicators of “root causes”. This paper introduces a non-linear model of an endogenous feedback affecting violent offenders that offers a novel possible explanation for such a lack of correlation.

There is less than perfect correlation between crime rates and their “root causes”. As James Q. Wilson (1975) observed many years ago, crime soared in the US in the 1960s even though it was a decade of prosperity that witnessed aggressive social interventions such as the “war on poverty”. Wilson dubbed this crime amidst plenty the “paradox of the 1960s”, but the paradox is not limited to the 1960s. During the Reagan-era economic expansion the unemployment rate fell steadily from a peak of 9.7% to 5.3%, but there was essentially no net change in the number of homicides.1 In other periods, such as the 1990s, crime and economic indicators move in tandem. Overall, though, between Wilson’s writing in 1975 and 2001 there was actually a slight negative correlation between the rates of unemployment and violence in the US.2

Lack of correlation does not stem from lack of variation. Homicide rates in the US doubled between 1960 and 1980 (from 5.1 to 10.2 per 100,000 population) then fell back almost to its original levels by 2000 (to 5.5 per 100,000). Nor do such simple statistics imply that root causes are irrelevant. Rather, the amplitude of variation and lack of correlation with traditional macro explanatory variables suggests the possibility of interesting internal dynamics and possibly indirect or lagged relationships between root causes and violence.

A variety of hypotheses along these lines have been advanced, including that violence toward children prompts those children to become violent offenders (Widom and Maxfield, 2001) and that variation in the availability of abortion affects the proportion of children who grow up to be violent offenders (Donohue and Levitt, 2001). Another hypothesis is that violence is inherently self-limiting because crime is most often committed within rather than across social groups. In particular, lethal violence may be perpetrated most often against people who are themselves criminally involved.3 In this vision of the world, epidemics of violence may burn themselves out by self-induced attrition of violent offenders. This paper proposes a formal model that captures this dynamic and explores some policy implications of trying to control optimally the cycles of violence that can occur in this model.

In a continuous time dynamic model, cycles cannot emerge with a single state variable, so the number of violent offenders must be augmented by some other quantity for non-monotonic variation to emerge. One possibility is that lethal interactions between violent offenders are much more likely within a general climate or expectation of violence than when the expectation is one of amicable co-existence and that this climate of violence is driven by recollection of actual instances of violence, not merely by counts of the current number of potential offenders. In other words, it is possible for a large number of potentially violent offenders to co-exist without killing each other in great numbers if there is a tradition of non-lethal interactions, but the expectation of violent interactions could itself be a violence promoter.

An expectation of violence can be a self-fulfilling prophecy for any of several reasons. For example, if a violence-prone individual perceives the world to be very risky, the individual might be more likely to carry a weapon, which in turn increases the likelihood confrontations will escalate to lethal violence (cf. Blumstein et al., 2000). Likewise, if one expects an adversary to attack, that increases the incentive to commit a preemptive first strike. Also, high levels of background violence might affect behavioral norms. In a society in which violence is rare, an individual might respond to an insult or challenge with words or fists, believing that more lethal actions are uncalled for.

This suggests analyzing a model with two states: the number of potentially violent offenders (x) and the perceived climate or expectation of violence (y). (Note that in what follows, whenever referring to the state variable y, we will simply call it the “climate of violence”.) One of the flows out of the population of potentially violent individuals is proportional (with proportionality constant α) to the square of the number of such individuals (as in predator–prey interactions, except that the predator and prey are the same species in this case) and to the climate of violence. Every such exit (representing a death) also generates an inflow to the climate of violence. Violent interactions between the offenders (x) and the general public (whose population is assumed to be constant) are also assumed to be both promoted by and contribute to this climate of violence (y), so there is a second inflow to y that is proportional (with proportionality constant β) to xy.

To focus attention on this dynamic, the rest of the model will be kept quite simple, with just a simple growth model for the offenders and exponential decay of the climate of violence (at a rate δ). In particular, individuals join the pool of violent offenders at a constant rate of k individuals per unit time, perhaps because a fixed proportion of every birth cohort has the capacity to be very violent, and there is a constant outflow or exit rate per person per unit time (μ) due to aging, death for other reasons, being incarcerated, etc. The exponential decay of the climate of violence is just a forgetting term, analogous to that in Behrens et al. (2002).

Formally the uncontrolled model can thus be written asx˙=k-μx-αx2y,y˙=αx2y+βxy-δy,where k, μ, α, β, and δ are positive constants.

Section snippets

The uncontrolled model

In this section we establish some basic properties of the descriptive (uncontrolled) model given by Eqs. (1), (2), where k, μ, α, β, δ are positive parameters. In particular, we investigate the dependence of the steady state of the system on these parameters, whose base values (denoted by k¯,,δ¯) are identified in Section 2.2.

Optimal control of the violence model

Governments take an active interest in trying to control crime and violence, because both high average levels and sharp variations in crime rates over time are costly. In this section we explore how a decision maker might intervene to control or shape the course of a violence epidemic governed by the dynamics described in the model above.

Conclusions

Violence can vary over time in ways that are not well-explained by exogenous factors such as changes in the unemployment rate, suggesting that there may be internal dynamics at work. One suggestion for such a dynamic is that violence begets violence, in the sense that a general climate of violence promotes hair trigger responses, preemptive strikes, and carrying of more powerful weapons, but this positive feedback is ultimately contained in a very direct manner. Since most crime occurs within

References (13)

  • D.A. Behrens et al.

    Why present-oriented societies undergo cycles of drug epidemics?

    Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control

    (2002)
  • J.-P. Aubin et al.

    Differential Inclusions

    (1984)
  • A. Blumstein et al.

    The rise and decline of homicide – and why

    Annual Review of Public Health

    (2000)
  • J.J. Donohue et al.

    The impact of legalized abortion on crime

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (2001)
  • G. Feichtinger et al.

    Optimale Kontrolle Ökonomischer Prozesse – Anwendungen des Maximumprinzips in den Wirtschaftswissenschaften

    (1986)
  • Greenwood, P.W., Rydell, C.P., Abrahamse, A.F., Caulkins, J.P., Chiesa, J., Model, K.E., Klein, S.P., 1994. Three...
There are more references available in the full text version of this article.

Cited by (2)

  • Preparing transitions in public services: Payoff dimension, value estimation, schedule and budget computation

    2016, Socio-Economic Planning Sciences
    Citation Excerpt :

    Optimizing scarce crime-fighting resources has been successfully applied in patrol officer scheduling as in Taylor and Huxley [18]. In addition, there are two recent studies on Cycles of violence by Caulkins et al. [3] and Optimizing counter-terror operations, by Caulkins et al. [4]. However, optimal prosecutor assignment to multiple locations has yet to be addressed.

  • Optimal control of nonlinear processes: With applications in drugs, corruption, and terror

    2008, Optimal Control of Nonlinear Processes: With Applications in Drugs, Corruption, and Terror

This research was partly supported by the Austrian Science Fund (FWF) under grant # P14060-G05. Support was provided also in part by a grant from the National Consortium on Violence Research (NCOVR), headquartered at the Heinz School of Public Policy and Management at Carnegie Mellon University. NCOVR is supported under grant # SBR 9513040 from the National Science Foundation in partnership with the US Department of Housing and Urban Development and the National Institute of Justice.

View full text