Persistent but not consistent: The growth of national income in Holland 1347–1807

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eeh.2011.11.002Get rights and content

Abstract

In this paper we construct a detailed dataset of the national accounts of Holland (1347–1807). Using this dataset, we demonstrate that this economy was characterized by persistent economic growth caused by, depending on the period, structural change (share of industry and services in the economy increases), technological development, and factor substitution. During the entire period GDP per capita increased by on average 0.19% per year. This persistent growth, however, was highly unstable due largely to the importance of international services in the economy.

Introduction

The debate about the character of economic growth before the Industrial Revolution of the late eighteenth century has gone through a number of stages. In the 1960s and 1970s the early modern economy of Europe was considered to be basically stagnant, a view that was most clearly expressed by Wilhelm Abel (Abel, 1966) and by the representatives of the French Annales school (e.g. Le Roy Ladurie, 1974). In the 1980s and 1990s this picture came under attack from several sides. Economic historians of the early modern period began to point out that the industrialization of the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries was made possible by structural changes that took place during preceding centuries. The development of urbanization and international trade networks (e.g. De Vries, 1984), agricultural productivity (e.g. de Vries, 1974, Hoffman, 1996), proto-industry (e.g. Mendels, 1972), national patterns of specialization (e.g. Kussmail, 1990) and labor markets (e.g. Lucassen, 1987), the ‘consumer revolution’ and the ‘industrious revolution’ (e.g. De Vries, 1994), all demonstrated that this was a dynamic period, when the basis was laid for the industrialization of Western Europe after c. 1780. This ‘revolt of the early modernists’, as Jan de Vries (1994, p. 253) has called it, has resulted in a much more optimistic interpretation of economic growth during the centuries before the Industrial Revolution.2 In their book on ‘The First Modern Economy. Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch Economy, 1500–1815’, Jan de Vries and Ad van der Woude have carried this ‘revolt of the early modernists’ to its logical conclusion. Their thesis is not only that The Netherlands in this period can be characterized as ‘the first modern economy’, but also that it went through a process (or rather a cycle) of ‘modern economic growth’ between 1500 and 1815 (De Vries and Van der Woude, 1997, p. 721).

This re-assessment of the early modern period has not gone unchallenged, however. The old orthodoxy that the pre 1800 world was basically a Malthusian one in which the welfare of the population was stagnant in the long run, has returned to the scene with the appearance of Greg Clark's (2007) 'A Farewell to Alms’, and the heated debate to which it gave rise.3 Clark mainly focused on English data and estimates – most importantly (and controversially)4 his estimates of the national income using the income approach (see also Clark (2010)) – and did not pay a lot of attention to what was happening in the rest of Europe, however.

So far, the answering of the questions about the growth trajectory of the European economy before industrialization has thus been severely constrained by data problems. The optimism of De Vries and Van der Woude is based on a few scattered data points concerning possible levels of income in the Dutch Republic (or Holland),5 whereas the pessimism by Clark (2010) is largely based on his national income series for England calculated via the income approach.6 What is missing, in our opinion, is a consistent set of estimates of the national accounts via the output approach of the European countries in the pre-1800 period, making it possible to study the process of economic growth in detail. A research project with the aim to put together these sets of estimates of long-term economic growth in Western Europe before the Industrial Revolution already started in the 1990s (initiated by Herman van der Wee and Angus Maddison),7 and is now reaching a stage in which detailed and annual estimates of GDP per capita for key regions in Western Europe are being put together such as for England, Italy, and Spain.8 This paper presents the results of such a project for Holland, the most populous and wealthy province of the Netherlands, for which relatively rich historical sources are available making it possible to construct annual estimates of GDP and its components.

The case of Holland is of obvious importance for the debate sketched in the Introduction. It was undoubtedly one of the most dynamic parts of Europe in the centuries before 1800 and had, as demonstrated by De Vries and Van der Woude (1997, pp. 693–699), already a relatively modern institutional framework. Their hypothesis of ‘a first round of modern economic growth’ is largely based on the case of this province. A reconstruction of the national accounts of the province should make it possible to answer the question if (and when) this region generated such a process. Or was its development a typical example of ‘Smithian’ growth, driven by the expansion of international trade and resulting from increased specialization and improved allocation of resources (e.g. Mokyr, 2010, p. 5)? Was it another example of the wave-like character of an ‘efflorescence’, typical of the pre industrial economy (e.g. Goldstone, 2002), which in the long run did not lead to a (much) higher level of GDP per capita? How important were ‘modern’ drivers of economic growth such as technological change and the accumulation of human and physical capital? And, assuming that De Vries and Van der Woude are correct that institutions in this part of the world were indeed remarkably modern already in the 16th and 17th centuries, why did this ‘first modern economy’ cease to generate growth and structural change after 1650 or 1670? Or did it continue to grow after 1670?

The focus on the province of Holland has big advantages: it was the most urbanized, dynamic and richest province of the Dutch Republic, and is therefore typical for the pattern of change that can be found in the most developed parts of Western Europe in this period.9 Studying this case informs us about the growth processes that were possible in this part of the European economy, which were not limited by the decreasing returns of the agricultural sector (because this sector was so small in this region). Moreover, we were also able to reconstruct the basic outlines of the growth trajectory of the Holland economy in the late Medieval period (between 1347 and 1500), which makes it possible to study a period in which structural transformation was dramatic and an important source of economic growth. By adding these 150 years to the growth record, we can also put the experience of this economy during its ‘Golden Age’ in perspective.

Finally, our intention is to chart the most important features of long term growth in Holland in this paper, focusing on its ‘proximate causes’; we do not intend to test ideas about its ‘ultimate causes’ from new institutional economics or unified growth theory.

Section snippets

The dataset

We think we are now closer to answering above questions, because we have built a detailed dataset of the national accounts of Holland between 1510 and 1807, and also developed a likely ‘scenario’ for the pace and character of economic growth during the late Medieval period. As a result, we can present estimates of the development of GDP per capita for the whole 1347–1807 period; this also includes estimates of the structure of the economy (the share of agriculture in GDP, for example). In

Structural change and growth between 1347 and 1510

Although per capita growth seemed to have taken place almost during the whole period, this does not imply that the character and sources of per capita growth remained the same over the entire period. Before we analyze the ‘proximate causes’ of growth in the period after 1500 in some detail, first a few words about the late Medieval period. This was without doubt a period of very rapid structural change. In the 1340s, between 50 and 55% of GDP originated in agriculture, and probably an even

The proximate causes of growth between 1510 and 1807

As a result of the dramatic decline of agriculture in the late medieval period, structural change in the next three centuries was rather limited. What happened between 1510 and 1807 – to make a long story short – was that the share of services in the labor force and in GDP increased strongly, which is what may be expected during economic development. Moreover, its relative productivity remained higher than in industry and agriculture, implying that this shift contributed to income growth. At

Conclusion

The central question of this article was about the character of economic growth before the Industrial Revolution: was there some kind of ‘first round of modern economic growth’, a sustained increase in income per capita accompanied by structural change? Or should we interpret the Dutch Golden Age as an example of the cyclical nature of growth in this period, of a brief efflorescence of the economy, inevitably followed by stagnation or even decline?

The answer to these questions was based on a

References (63)

  • Robert C. Allen

    The great divergence in European wages and prices

    Explorations in Economic History

    (2001)
  • Michal Jerzmanowski

    Empirics of hills, plateaus, mountains and plains: a Markov-switching approach to growth

    Journal of Development Economics

    (2006)
  • Jan Luiten Van Zanden et al.

    Roots of growth and productivity change in Dutch shipping industry, 1500–1800

    Explorations in Economic History

    (2009)
  • Wilhelm Abel

    Agrarkrisen Und Agrarkonjunktur

    Eine Geschichte Der Land- Und Ernährungswirtschaft Mitteleuropas Seitdem Hohen Mittelalter

    (1966)
  • Donald Andrews

    Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point

    Econometrica

    (1993)
  • Bang, Nina.E., Knut. Korst, 1906/1953. Tabeller over Skibsvart og Varetransport gennem Oresund. Copenhagen, Gyldendal,...
  • Bas Van Bavel

    Early proto-industrialization in the low countries? The importance and nature of market-oriented non-agricultural activities in the countryside in Flanders and Holland, c. 1250–1570

    Revue belge de philologie et d'histoire

    (2003)
  • Bas Van Bavel et al.

    The jump start of the Holland economy during the late medieval crisis, c 1350–1500

    Economic History Review

    (2004)
  • Jan Blomme et al.

    The Belgian economy in a long-term perspective

  • Dick De Boer

    Graaf en Grafiek

    Sociale en Economische ontwikkelingen in het middeleeuwse ‘Noordhollland’ tussen ± 1345 and ± 1415

    (1978)
  • Stephen Broadberry et al.

    British economic growth, 1300–1850: some preliminary estimates

  • Stephen Broadberry et al.

    The sectoral distribution of the labour force and labour productivity in Britain, 1381–1851

  • Eltjo Buringh et al.

    Charting the “rise of the west” manuscripts and printed books in Europe, a long-term perspective from the sixth through eighteenth centuries

    Journal of Economic History

    (2009)
  • Agatha L. Chapman

    Wages and Salaries in the United Kingdom 1920–1938

    (1953)
  • Hollis Chenery et al.

    Patterns of Development, 1950–1970

    (1975)
  • Gregory Clark

    A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World

    (2007)
  • Gregory Clark

    The macroeconomic aggregates for England, 1209–2008

    Research in Economic History

    (2010)
  • Nicholas Crafts

    British Economic Growth During the Industrial Revolution

    (1985)
  • Karel Davids

    The Rise and Decline of Dutch Technological Leadership: Technology, Economy, and Culture in the Netherlands, 1350–1800

    (2008)
  • Johannes Gerard Van Dillen

    Mensen en achtergronden

    (1964)
  • Charles H. Feinstein et al.

    A plea for errors

    Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History, Number 41

    (2001)
  • Wantje Fritschy et al.

    Gewestelijke Financiën ten tijde van de Republiek der Verenigde Nederlanden, deel 4: Holland, 1572–1795

    (2004)
  • Jack A. Goldstone

    Efflorescences and economic growth in world history: rethinking the “rise of the west” and the industrial revolution

    Journal of World History

    (2002)
  • Knick Harley

    Gregory Clarks a farewell to alms

    Economic History Review

    (2008)
  • Philip T. Hoffman

    Growth in a Traditional Society: The French Countryside, 1450–1815

    (1996)
  • Edwin Horlings

    The Economic Development of the Dutch Service Sector 1800–1850

    (1995)
  • Jonathan Israel

    Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 1585–1740

    (1989)
  • Michael Jansen

    De industriële ontwikkeling in Nederland, 1800–1850

    (1999)
  • Ann Kussmaul

    A General View of the Rural Economy of England, 1538–1840

    (1990)
  • J.P. de Korte

    De Jaarlijkse financiële verantwoording in de VOC Verenigde Oostindische Compagnie

    (1984)
  • Bas Van Leeuwen

    Human Capital and Economic Growth in India, Indonesia, and Japan: A Quantitative Analysis, 1890–2000

    (2007)
  • Cited by (139)

    • War, pandemics, and modern economic growth in Europe

      2022, Explorations in Economic History
    • Economic Growth in Germany, 1500-1850

      2022, Journal of Economic History
    View all citing articles on Scopus
    1

    Tel: + 31 30 2536458.

    View full text