Elsevier

Ecological Economics

Volume 159, May 2019, Pages 226-234
Ecological Economics

Analysis
Market Redirection Leakage in the Palm Oil Market

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2019.01.014Get rights and content

Highlights

  • Unilateral tariffs or bans on palm oil imports, to limit importation of deforestation, lead to market redirection leakage.

  • Combining tariffs with output subsidies can reduce leakage.

  • Reducing transaction costs of switching to forest friendly production complements output subsidies in reducing leakage

Abstract

Tropical deforestation and forest degradation (DD) are linked to international trade in commodities like palm oil, and implicated in biodiversity loss and global greenhouse emissions. Regulations to save these forests, including embodied DD tariffs or bans on unsustainably produced imports, are typically fragmented, permitting DD activities to find coverage gaps and create DD leakage. The forestry literature has focused on the competitiveness leakage channel, with DD implicated production shifting from strictly to laxly regulated jurisdictions. Less recognized is the market redirection channel. Production need not move. Instead, sales are rerouted to less selective markets. Using the example of palm oil, we develop a model in which one importing region imposes an embodied DD tariff. Some exporters may face transaction costs to switch to low DD production. With a common DD tariff policy across all importers being both improbable and burdensome to exporters, we investigate unilateral approaches. Contrary to a unilateral ban, or tariff, on unsustainable imports, which creates market redirection leakage, the second best optimum combines the unilateral damage based tariff with an output subsidy. The output subsidy encourages exports to the tariffed market.

Introduction

Reducing tropical deforestation and forest degradation (DD) in developing countries is essential to limit global warming and preserve biodiversity (Stern, 2007; Seymour and Busch, 2016; Giam, 2017). Clearing for export-oriented agricultural commodities is a driver of tropical deforestation. Curtis et al. (2018) estimate that globally about 27% of all forest disturbance between 2001 and 2015 was commodity driven. Palm and soybean production are examples that are implicated in countries such as Malaysia, Indonesia and Brazil (Carlson et al., 2018; Curtis et al., 2018).

Developing countries often lack the capacity or motivation to curb DD on their own. Assistance and/or pressure from regulations imposed by developed country importers can help, but diverse application across jurisdictions offers fragmented coverage, leaving leakage channels through which DD can be maintained. The forestry literature has emphasized the competitive leakage channel; differential imposition of regulations on suppliers of forest products, promoting the geographical displacement of DD implicated production from more to less strictly regulated jurisdictions (Murray et al., 2004; Gan and McCarl, 2007; Lim et al., 2017). It can be avoided by uniform application of regulations across all sources of supply. We focus on a leakage channel not well recognized for forest products, the market redirection channel that occurs when regulations are applied differentially across markets. Producers need not move, but instead create leakage by rerouting their sales to less selective markets. In energy markets it is known as the energy market channel (Bohm, 1993; Larch et al., 2018).

Using the example of palm oil as the product, and a DD embodied tariff as the main regulatory instrument, we develop a model in which not all importers are concerned about the forest loss embodied in their imports, nor willing to impose embodied DD tariffs. We also allow that, due to transaction costs, not all developing country exporters respond to importing country tariffs by switching to forest friendly production practices. In the unlikely event that all importers imposed tariffs, market redirection leakage would be avoided. Contrary to a unilateral ban, or tariff, on unsustainable imports, which creates market redirection leakage, the second best optimum combines the unilateral damage based tariff with an output subsidy. The output subsidy encourages exports to the tariffed market. If transaction costs are sufficiently low the exports to the tariffed market will also be sustainably produced.

The next section provides background on the palm oil market. Section 3 discusses the literature on leakage. Section 4 models four importing or exporting entities in the palm oil market; an embodied DD tariff imposing oil importer, an importer that does not impose the tariff, an exporter who always responds to the tariff by producing sustainably, and a competing exporter who, depending on the transaction costs of certifying sustainable production, will produce all or a portion of its production unsustainably. Section 5 presents policy recommendations.

Section snippets

The Palm Oil Market

Palm oil is traded globally and accounts 34% of world vegetable oil production. Soybean oil, at 29%, is its closest competitor (United States Department of Agriculture, 2017). Along with rapeseed and sunflower oils they are effectively interchangeable for edible (e.g. sweets, baked goods, margarine, cereals), non-edible (e.g. detergents, and cosmetics) and biofuel uses (Corley, 2009).

Indonesia and Malaysia account for about 56% and 35% of all palm oil exports (United States Department of

Leakage

Leakage occurs when there is an incomplete regulatory framework for pollution, with unregulated market segments providing channels that allow polluting economic activities to avoid the regulation (Holland, 2012; Lim et al., 2017). It is defined as pollution levels different from, usually in excess of, what would occur with no response in unregulated market segments to restrictions in the regulated segments. Because forests provide global public goods such as biodiversity and carbon

Model With Market Redirection Leakage

We use a simple model with two representative palm oil importing jurisdictions, r and n, and two representative palm oil exporting firms, x and y, in a different jurisdiction(s). There may be other domestic production and consumption within these jurisdictions. For simplicity, we assume that all other consumption, production and associated pollution is fixed, and that for both importing regions willingness to pay is additively separable in palm oil and any other products consumed. The market

Palm Oil Policies

We have shown that a DD tariff imposed unilaterally by an importer causes market redirection leakage to non-tariffed markets that may well prevent much reduction in unsustainable production. We have also shown that an output subsidy can be used to reduce leakage from tariffed to non-tariffed markets, but that it may not be very effective in reducing unsustainable production if transaction costs prevent unsustainable producers from switching to sustainable production. If transaction costs can be

References (65)

  • S. Felder et al.

    Unilateral CO2 reductions and carbon leakage: the consequences of international trade in oil and basic materials

    J. Environ. Econ. Manag.

    (1993)
  • C. Fischer et al.

    Climate policy and fiscal constraints: do tax interactions outweigh carbon leakage?

    Energy Econ.

    (2012)
  • J. Gan et al.

    Measuring transnational leakage of forest conservation

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2007)
  • R. Gerlagh et al.

    Spill or leak? Carbon leakage with international technology spillovers: a CGE analysis

    Energy Econ.

    (2014)
  • M. Hoel

    Efficient climate policy in the presence of free riders

    J. Environ. Econ. Manag.

    (1994)
  • S.P. Holland

    Emissions taxes versus intensity standards: second-best environmental policies with incomplete regulation

    J. Environ. Econ. Manag.

    (2012)
  • M.L. Ingalls et al.

    The transboundary displacement of deforestation under REDD+: problematic intersections between the trade of forest-risk commodities and land grabbing in the Mekong region

    Glob. Environ. Chang.

    (2018)
  • M. Larch et al.

    Can degrowth overcome the leakage problem of unilateral climate policy?

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2018)
  • J.F. Lund et al.

    Promising change, delivering continuity: REDD+ as conservation fad

    World Dev.

    (2017)
  • I. Mukherjee et al.

    Palm oil-based biofuels and sustainability in southeast Asia: a review of Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand

    Renew. Sust. Energ. Rev.

    (2014)
  • D. Pearce et al.

    Sustainable forestry in the tropics: panacea or folly?

    For. Ecol. Manag.

    (2003)
  • D. Ruysschaert et al.

    Towards global voluntary standards: questioning the effectiveness in attaining conservation goals: the case of the Roundtable on Sustainable Palm Oil (RSPO)

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2014)
  • A.I. Ugochukwu et al.

    Technological solutions to authenticity issues in international trade: the case of CITES listed endangered species

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2018)
  • M. Alias et al.

    Supply response of Malaysian palm oil producers: impact of interest rate variations

    Oil Palm Industry Economic Journal

    (2005)
  • A. Angelsen et al.

    Learning from REDD+: a response to Fletcher et al

    Conserv. Biol.

    (2017)
  • K. Baylis et al.

    Negative leakage

    J. Assoc. Environ. Resour. Econ.

    (2014)
  • C. Böhringer et al.

    Robust policies to mitigate carbon leakage

    J. Public Econ.

    (2017)
  • C. Böhringer et al.

    Embodied carbon tariffs

    Scand. J. Econ.

    (2018)
  • K.M. Carlson et al.

    Effect of oil palm sustainability certification on deforestation and fire in Indonesia

    Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci.

    (2018)
  • B. Cashore et al.

    Forest certification in developing and transitioning countries: part of a sustainable future?

    Environ. Sci. Policy Sustain. Dev.

    (2006)
  • P.G. Curtis et al.

    Classifying drivers of global forest loss

    Science

    (2018)
  • P. Dauvergne

    Is the power of brand-focused activism rising? The case of tropical deforestation

    The Journal of Environment & Development

    (2017)
  • Cited by (13)

    • Shared and environmentally just responsibility for global biodiversity loss

      2022, Ecological Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      However, the EU will only aim to identify the main drivers of biodiversity loss from 2021 onwards and is yet to take any overarching action to directly prevent biodiversity decline along trade networks (European Commission, 2019). Adding biodiversity conservation costs onto the price of goods, or levying a tariff to protect biodiversity are potential ways to allocate biodiversity conservation responsibility while limiting leakage (Wilman, 2019). The financial support for biodiversity protection efforts is not sufficient.

    • Harnessing relational values for global value chain sustainability: Reframing the roundtable on sustainable palm oil's offset mechanism to support smallholders

      2022, Ecological Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Based on a logistic regression model (not shown), these respondents are more likely to be headquartered in North America, Europe, and Australia, a finding consistent with negative perceptions of credits in those regions. Amid growing debates about the relative merits of environmental tariffs, bans, or zero-deforestation supply chain commitments targeting sectors driving deforestation, there is some evidence that strategies that combine restrictions on unsustainably produced goods with subsidies for sustainable production can be effective in avoiding leakage due to market switching (Wilman, 2019). If this is the case, then maintaining mechanisms that can direct such market signals and support upstream producers could remain an important part of sustainability strategies.

    • Rethinking zero deforestation beyond 2020 to more equitably and effectively conserve tropical forests

      2020, One Earth
      Citation Excerpt :

      Excluding the Soy Moratorium, most ZD commitments lack biome-wide implementation, and none has attained global market coverage.39 This limits impact, as producers can redirect commodities to less-selective markets if ZD-committed customers cease buying from them.99 Government support, an important predictor of success for private-sector sustainability initiatives, is often lacking in commodity-producing regions52 due to conflict with national development goals and concerns about national sovereignty.78

    • Tri-fuel emulsion with secondary atomization attributes for greener diesel engine – A critical review

      2019, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews
      Citation Excerpt :

      In the South East Asia context, palm oil is still the primary raw source for biodiesel production and one of the most significant feedstocks in the world. Unfortunately, the future of palm oil feedstock currently under pressure by the European Union proposed palm oil ban campaign due to mass deforestation issue [112,113]. The phase-out attempt on one of the major biodiesel feedstocks not only obstruction to the biofuel campaign but also an add-on to the current state of struggling with demand fluctuations and lack of proper marketing of biodiesel from the automotive industry.

    • From the Climate-energy Conundrum to the Climate-energy-land Nexus

      2023, The Climate-Energy-Land Nexus in Indonesia Biofuel, REDD+ and biochar
    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text