Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Governance through government networks: The G8 and international organizations

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

As an informal grouping without headquarters, permanent staff or legal powers, the world’s major industrialized countries must rely on other actors, in particular international organizations, to manage global problems. This article examines how the Group of Eight contributes to global governance by cooperating with international organizations in the cases of debt relief and the fight against terrorist finance. It shows that the G8 draws on international institutions with the aid of government networks and argues that this cooperation is stronger, the greater the Group’s concentration of relevant power and the more important it considers the institutions’ resources.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Russia became a formal member of the “political G8” in 1998, but it only obtained full and equal membership of the “economic G8” in 2006. In this article the term G8 is used unless it is essential to make a distinction between the G8 and the G7.

  2. The financial sous-sherpas deal with topics such as monetary policy, debt and the international financial architecture, the foreign affairs sous-sherpas talk about environmental and development issues, and the political affairs directors (also from the ministries of foreign affairs) discuss regional questions, arms control, the fight against terrorism and drug trafficking.

  3. The Group of Twenty is an informal forum of the finance ministers and central bank governors of 19 industrialized and emerging-market countries plus the European Union (EU) that promotes a dialogue on key issues related to global economic stability.

  4. A notable exception is Ashgate’s “The G8 and Global Governance Series” published since 1999 under the auspices of the “G8 Research Group” of the University of Toronto. See also Gstöhl (2003).

  5. I thereby use global governance in an analytical sense (i.e., how it works empirically), not in a normative sense (prescribing value-based solutions to global problems).

  6. Exceptions are Putnam and Bayne (1987: 160–166), Bayne (2000: 137–141) and a few specific case studies (e.g., Kühne, 2000; Cohn, 2002; Fratianni, Savona, & Kirton, 2002; Penttilä, 2003; Baker, 2006).

  7. The Group’s first official “outreach” dialogue with civil society took place in 1998. In addition, a few G8 expert groups have in recent years brought in private actors.

  8. Bailin (2001: 16–18) argues that a “group hegemon” requires a group identity which in the case of the G8 is established by the small number of participants, by restricting membership to capitalist democracies sharing a mutual interest in maintaining the liberal economic order, and by the Group’s public recognition accomplished through well-publicized great power summits. Volgy, Frazier, and Ingersoll (2003: 63) conclude on the basis of an analysis of G7 voting patterns in the UN General Assembly “that the group remains a strongly cohesive force.”

  9. While “transnational” means relaxing the assumption that states are the only relevant actors in world politics, “transgovernmental” means relaxing the assumption that states act as units. Keohane and Nye (1974: 43–44) do not regard heads-of-state meetings as transgovernmental politics but only activities of lower-level bureaucracies. For the purpose of this article, however, the summits themselves are also considered part of transgovernmental relations. After all, heads of state or government do not necessarily represent a single position of the entire government apparatus but may, for instance, employ a two-level strategy to overcome domestic opposition (see Putnam, 1988: 457).

  10. Policy networks may be defined as a set of relatively stable relationships which are of a non-hierarchical and interdependent nature linking a variety of actors who share common interests with regard to a policy and who exchange resources to pursue these shared interests (Börzel, 1998: 254).

  11. In Slaughter’s stricter conception, vertical government networks involve only “supranational” institutions, that is, where international organizations have become sufficiently specialized to develop the equivalent of an executive, judicial, or even legislative branch.

  12. Early in the summit process, leaders of international organizations were not invited because heads of state considered international secretariats and national bureaucracies alike part of the problem, not the solution (Schaetzel & Malmgren, 1980: 140). From today’s perspective, Baker (2006: 136) argues that “while the Managing Director is supposed to communicate the rest of the world’s interests to the G7, it is more common for the G7 to attempt to use the IMF and the Managing Director to express their views to the rest of the world.”

  13. Since 1977 the EU participates in the summits and is represented by the Commission and the country holding the Presidency (in case of a non-G8 EU member). It cannot assume the presidency.

  14. The “G8 Research Group” defines a commitment as a discrete, specific, publicly expressed, collectively agreed statement of intent, a “promise” or “undertaking” by summit members that they will take action to move toward, meet or adjust to an identified target (such as changes in the behavior of members, other countries, international institutions or private actors). See http://www.g8.utoronto.ca/evaluations/methodology/g7c2.htm (download 20/05/2006). Ougaard (2004: 78f) suggests to use the number of references to an organization in G8 summit declarations as an (admittedly crude) indicator. The number does, however, not inform us about the contents or importance of the aspired cooperation.

  15. Baker (2006: 11) finds that G7 influence is “based on activities such as discourse construction, the promotion of shared causal and normative beliefs, mutual endorsement, persuasion and ultimately attempts to legitimate existing arrangements.”

  16. The concept of policy export draws on EU literature regarding the accession and association processes (e.g., Christiansen, Petito, & Tonra, 2000).

  17. Strictly speaking, the G8 demands made upon an international organization in summit declarations do not qualify as delegations in terms of the principal-agent theory. Such a definition of delegation implies a conditional grant of authority from a principal to an agent empowering the latter to act on behalf of the former, a relationship governed by a contract (cf. Hawkins et al., 2006-12-12) As members of an international organization, the G8 states have, of course, upon their accession delegated authority and they are able to revoke it, but this act is not linked to the summit requests. Moreover, policy networks are of a non-hierarchical nature.

  18. According to Keohane (1984: 51), this kind of “cooperation requires that the actions of separate individuals or organizations—which are not in pre-existent harmony—be brought into conformity with one another through a process of negotiation, which is often referred to as ‘policy coordination’.”

  19. For the purpose of this study, and for reasons of clarity, I distinguish between the notions of “power” and “resources”: whereas the G8 holds power, the other institutions dispose of resources.

  20. From an International Relations perspective, this conception corresponds to the neoliberal institutionalist view that policies are largely shaped by an actor’s relative power position in a given issue area and its relative influence in an international institution.

  21. The budget share is especially of interest as a supplementary indicator with regard to organizations based on the principle of “one country, one vote.” In fact, a budget’s scale assessments are often associated with issue-specific power.

  22. Arts (2001: 44) defines resources as “facilities to which policy coalitions (may) have access and which coalitions mobilise to influence the course of action in a policy domain.”

  23. If international secretariats are members of (vertical) government networks, “their distinctive resources tend to be information and an aura of international legitimacy” (Keohane & Nye, 1974: 52).

  24. From an International Relations perspective, the perceived relevance of resources introduces a constructivist element. Moreover, legitimacy is socially constructed.

  25. Regarding the two independent variables, the importance of resources weighs in more heavily than the Group´s power concentration because the G8 has no reason to cooperate with international institutions if it expects no benefits from doing so.

  26. Baker (2006: 234–238) finds that in global financial governance the U.S. retains a pre-eminent position in the G7 but has been constrained by growing market authority and shared multilateral norms.

  27. The Group maintains no own expert groups in the field of debt relief. Initially, finance ministers met annually at the summit site. The 1986 Tokyo summit officially set up the G7 finance ministers´ group as a separate entity that meets four or more times a year, usually attended also by the central bank governors and often by the Managing Director of the IMF.

  28. Russia has pledged to repay its debts to the Paris Club in full by the end of 2006, and it has already prepaid debts to the IMF, owing to the soaring energy prices.

  29. cf. World Bank, World Development Indicators; OECD Development Assistance Committee online database; and IMF, International Financial Statistics Yearbook, various years.

  30. This article only considers debt owed to public creditors since governments or international organizations cannot forgive debts owed to private creditors.

  31. The World Bank classification of SILICs is not completely identical with that of the HIPCs, but there is a 90% overlap between the two groups.

  32. International organizations such as the OECD or the Bretton Woods institutions publish statistics on the debts of individual countries but, unfortunately, no information on the individual creditors.

  33. cf. IMF, Annual Reports of the Executive Board, various years.

  34. Obviously, if acting as a group, the G7 might exercise a veto as well.

  35. cf. World Bank, Annual Reports, various years.

  36. Permanent members are the G7 countries, Austria, Australia, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Ireland, The Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, and since 1997 Russia. Other creditors may join for specific negotiations. Since 1974 the Club maintains a secretariat in Paris (http://www.clubdeparis.org). Rescheduling for private debts takes place in the so-called London Club.

  37. Statements may also be issued by the other observers (World Bank, OECD, UNCTAD, EU, regional development banks), but the IMF opinion is of crucial importance. Since 1966 an agreement with the IMF has been considered a precondition for rescheduling debts in the Paris Club.

  38. All G7/G8 documents subsequently cited are available at http://www.g8.utoronto.ca/summit or http://www.g8.utoronto.ca/meetings.html.

  39. For example, in exchange for forgiving part of Mexico’s debt, the (reduced) principal and interest of the new bonds banks received were securitized by U.S. Treasury bonds.

  40. At the 1989 Paris summit, for instance, the G7 leaders underlined that “banks should increasingly focus on voluntary, market-based debt and debt-service reduction operations, as a complement to new lending.”

  41. The “Toronto terms” for the poorest debtor countries came close to the “Brady terms” earlier on offered to the middle-income debtor countries mainly from Latin America.

  42. The initiative is open to the poorest countries that: (1) are eligible only for highly concessional assistance such as from the IDA and the IMF’s ESAF; (2) face an unsustainable debt situation even after the full application of traditional debt relief mechanisms; and (3) have a proven track record in implementing strategies focused on reducing poverty and building the foundation for sustainable economic growth. In 1996, 41 countries were eligible under the HIPC initiative. See http://www.worldbank.org/debt and http://www.imf.org/external/np/hipc.

  43. Reaching the decision points means that all creditors commit to a debt relief (to be delivered at the completion point) in order to bring the debt to a sustainable level.

  44. In addition, about 70% of the bilateral donor pledges to the HIPC Trust Fund came from the G7 (IMF & IDA, 2004).

  45. The Millennium goal to develop “a global partnership for development” calls for an enhanced program of debt relief for heavily indebted poor countries and cancellation of official bilateral debt.

  46. The African Development Fund provides development finance on concessional terms to member countries which are unable to borrow on the normal terms of the African Development Bank.

  47. Unfortunately, Baker spends only four pages on official debt relief in his pioneering book on the G7’s role in global financial governance, even though he considers it “an area in which the finance ministries have had most scope to take action independently of other actors” (Baker, 2006: 222).

  48. http://www.fatf-gafi.org “Money Laundering FAQ” (download 20/05/2006).

  49. The G7 countries rank low on the Corruption Perceptions Index provided by Transparency Internationalhttp://www.transparency.org/cpi).

  50. U.S. Department of State, Patterns of Global Terrorism, various years.

  51. http://www.tkb.org

  52. cf. UN, Yearbook of the United Nations, various years. In the long run, it seems unlikely that the richest members finance decisions against their own interests taken by a majority of developing countries in the UN General Assembly. In the informal “Geneva Group” the 14 largest contributors to the UN and UN specialized agencies—among them all G8 countries—monitor the budgets to which they contribute over 80%.

  53. Information provided by the OECD Budget and Finance Service.

  54. http://www.un.org/terrorism

  55. Many years later, the UNODC has in 1997 established a Global Programme against Money Laundering and in 2002 a Global Programme against Terrorism.

  56. The summit also gave the group an open-ended mandate to implement the recommendations in the G8 states and, where possible, throughout the world. The Lyon Group has since developed numerous specialized sub-working groups which are involved in preparing the meetings of the G8 justice and interior ministers and report to the summits from which they receive new tasks.

  57. In addition, the G8 countries announced new non-proliferation measures (e.g. action plans on securing radioactive materials, tanker safety or the transport security and control of Man-Portable Air Defence Systems). The summit in Sea Island in 2004 added a G8 Secure and Facilitated International Travel Initiative.

  58. In May 2006 the Secretary-General presented the corresponding report (UN General Assembly, 2006).

  59. As many emerging market countries are turning into net creditors themselves, the Paris Club is also looking for new members (Financial Times, 2006).

References

  • Antholis, W. J. (2001). Pragmatic engagement or photo-op: What will the G-8 become?. The Washington Quarterly, 24(3), 213–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arts, B. (2001). International policy arrangements of state and non-state actors. In B. Arts, M. Noortmann, & B. Reinalda (Eds.), Non-state actors in international relations (pp. 41–58). Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailin, A. (2001). From traditional to institutionalized hegemony. G8 Governance 6.

  • Baker, A. (2006). The group of seven: Finance ministries, central banks and global financial governance. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, M., & Duvall, R. (2005). Power in international politics. International Organization, 59(1), 39–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, M. N., & Finnemore, M. (2004). Rules for the world: International organizations in global politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

  • Barry, T. (2002). G8: Failing model of global governance. Foreign Policy In Focus, 7(9).

  • Bayne, N. (2000). Hanging in there: The G7 and G8 summit in maturity and renewal. Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belelieu, A. (2002). The G8 and terrorism: What role can the G8 play in the 21st century? G8 Governance, 8.

  • Börzel, T. A. (1998). Organizing Babylon: On the different conceptions of policy networks. Public Administration, 76, 253–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiansen, T., Petito, F., & Tonra, B. (2000). Fuzzy politics around fuzzy borders: The European Union’s ‘near abroad.’ Cooperation and Conflict, 35(4), 389–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohn, T. H. (2002). Governing global trade: International institutions in conflict and convergence. Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Commission on Global Governance. (1995). Our global neighbourhood: The report of the Commission on Global Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eberlei, W. (1999a). Deutsche Gläubigerpolitik gegenüber ärmsten Ländern. Hamburg: Deutsches Übersee-Institut.

  • Eberlei, W. (1999b). Schuldenkrise ärmster Länder gelöst? Die Ergebnisse des Kölner G-7-Gipfels. INEF-Report 40, Duisburg: Institut für Entwicklung und Frieden der Gerhard-Mercator-Universität Duisburg.

  • English, J., Thakur, R., & Cooper, A. F. (Eds.) (2005). Reforming from the Top: A Leaders20 Summit. Tokyo: United Nations University Press.

  • Eurodad (2001). Eurodad latest bilateral creditor positions, (July). http://www.eurodad.org/uploadstore/cms/docs/creditor_matrix.pdf (download 20/05/2006).

  • Evans, H. (1999). Debt relief for the poorest countries: Why did it take so long? Development Policy Review, 17(3), 267–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Financial Times (2006). Paris Club marks half-century with rethink, (15 June).

  • Fratianni, M., & Pattison, J. (2005). Who is running the IMF: Critical shareholders or the Staff? In P. de Gijsel & H. Schenk (Eds.), Multidisciplinary economics: The birth of a new economics faculty in The Netherlands (pp. 279–292). Berlin Heidelberg New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fratianni, M., Savona, P., & Kirton, J. J. (Eds.) (2002). Governing global finance: New challenges, G7 and IMF contributions. Aldershot: Ashgate.

  • Gilligan, G. P. (2004). Overview: Markets, offshore sovereignty and onshore legitimacy. In D. Masciandaro (Ed.), Global financial crime: Terrorism, money laundering and offshore centres (pp. 7–59). Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gstöhl, S. (2003) (Ed.). Global Governance und die G8: Gipfelimpulse für Weltwirtschaft und Weltpolitik. Münster: LIT Verlag.

  • de Guttry, A. (1994). The institutional configuration of the G-7 in the new international scenario. The International Spectator, 29(2), 67–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hajnal, P. (2002). Partners or adversaries? The G7/G8 encounters civil society. In J. J. Kirton & J. Takase (Eds.), New directions in global political governance: The G8 and international order in the twenty-first century (pp. 209–222). Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawkins, D. G., Lake, D., Nielson, D., Tierney, M. (2006). States, International Organizations, and Principal-Agent theory. In D.G. Hawkins, et al. (Eds.), Delegation and agency in international organizations. Delagations under anarchy: States, international organizations, and principal-agent theory (pp. 3–38). New York: Cambridge University Press.

  • Héritier, A. (2002). New modes of governance in Europe: Policy-making without legislating? In A. Héritier (Ed.), Common goods: Reinventing European and international governance (pp. 185–206). Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschmann, K. (2000). The changing face of terrorism. Internationale Politik und Gesellschaft, 7(3), 299–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF. Annual Reports of the Executive Board. Washington, D.C., various years.

  • IMF. International Financial Statistics Yearbook. Washington, D.C., various years.

  • IMF (2005). IMF to Extend 100 Percent Debt Relief for 19 Countries Under the Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative, IMF Press Release no. 05/286, 21 December 2005.

  • IMF, & IDA (2004). Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative-Statistical Update, 31 March 2004.

  • IMF, & IDA (2006). Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative-Statistical Update, 21 March 2006.

  • IMF, & World Bank (2004). Twelve-Month Pilot Program of Anti-Money Laundering and Combating the Financing of Terrorism (AML/CFT) Assessments. Joint Report on the Review of the Pilot Program, 10 March 2004.

  • Kahler, M. (2006). Internal governance and IMF performance. In E. M. Truman (Ed.), Reforming the IMF for the 21st century (pp. 257–270). Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R. O. (1984). After hegemony: Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R. O. & Nye, J. S. (1974). Transgovernmental relations and international organizations. World Politics, 27(1), 39–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirton, J. J. (1999). Explaining G8 effectiveness. In M. Hodges, J. J. Kirton, & J. P. Daniels (Eds.), The G8s role in the new millennium (pp. 45–68). Aldershot: Ashgate,.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kokotsis, E., & Daniels, J. P. (1999). G8 summits and compliance. In M. Hodges, J. J. Kirton, & J. P. Daniels (Eds.), The G8s role in the new millennium (pp. 75–91). Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kühne, W. (2000). The security council and the G8 in the new millennium: who is in charge of international peace and security? Ebenhausen: Stiftung Wissenschaft und Politik.

  • Martin, P. (2005). A global answer to global problems. Foreign Affairs, 84(3), 2–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Naumann, J. (1994). Sieben für alle? Die Wahrnehmung des UN-Systems durch die G-7. Vereinte Nationen, 42(6), 207–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neuneck, G. (2000). Terrorismus und Massenvernichtungswaffen: eine neue Symbiose?. In K. Hirschmann & P. Gerhard (Eds.), Terrorismus als weltweites Phänomen (pp. 129–178). Berlin: Berlin Verlag Arno Spitz.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD Development Assistance Committee online database.

  • Ougaard, M. (2002). Global polity research: Characteristics and challenges. In M. Ougaard & R. Higgott (Eds.), Towards a global polity (pp. 23–39). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ougaard, M. (2004). Political globalization: State, power and social forces. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

  • Penttilä, R. E. J. (2003). The role of the G8 in international peace and security. Oxford: Oxford University Press for The International Institute for Strategic Studies.

  • Prantl, J. (2005). Informal groups of states and the UN Security Council. International Organization, 59(3), 559–592.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. D. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: The logic of two-level games. International Organization, 42(3), 427–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. D., & Bayne, N. (1987). Hanging together: Cooperation and conflict in the seven-power summits. Cambridge; MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rieffel, L. (2003). Restructuring sovereign debt: The case for ad hoc machinery. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Risse-Kappen, T. (Ed.) (1995). Bringing transnational relations back in: Non-state actors, domestic structures and international institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Schaetzel, J. R., & Malmgren, H. B. (1980). Talking heads. Foreign Policy, 39, 130–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmid, A. P., & Jongman, A. J. (1988). Political terrorism: A new guide to actors, authors, concepts, data bases, theories and literature. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmunk, M. (2000). Ein neuer ’Global Player’? Möglichkeiten und Grenzen der G8-Aussenminister. Internationale Politik, 55(8), 59–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slaughter, A.-M. (2001). Global Government Networks, Global Information Agencies, and Disaggregated Democracy. Harvard Law School Working Paper 018.

  • Slaughter, A.-M. (2004). A new world order. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • UN. Yearbook of the United Nations, New York, various years.

  • UN General Assembly (2005). 2005 World Summit Outcome, A/60/L.1, 20 September 2005.

  • UN General Assembly (2006). Uniting against terrorism: recommendations for a global counter-terrorism strategy, A/60/825, 27 April 2006.

  • UN Security Council (2005). Resolution 1617, S/RES/1617 (2005), 29 July 2005.

  • UN Secretary-General (2005). Secretary-Generals Keynote Address to the Closing Plenary of the International Summit on Democracy, Terrorism and Security—“A Global Strategy for Fighting Terrorism”, 10 March 2005.

  • U.S. Department of State. Patterns of Global Terrorism, Washington, D.C.: Office of the Coordinator for Counterterrorism, various years.

  • Volgy, T. J., & Bailin, A. (2003). International politics and state strength. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volgy, T. J., Frazier, D. V., & Ingersoll, R. S. (2003). Preference similarities and group hegemony: G-7 voting cohesion in the UN General Assembly. Journal of International Relations & Development, 6(1), 51–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Furstenberg, G. (2005). Terrorist finance: Within the grip of the G8?. In M. Fratianni, et al. (Eds.), New perspectives on global governance: Why America needs the G8 (pp. 193–202). Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walter, G., Dreher, S., & Beisheim, M. (1999). Globalisation processes in the G7. Global Society, 13(3), 229–255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, P. (2001). Crime, illicit markets, and money laundering. In P. J. Simmons & C. de Jonge Oudraat (Eds.), Managing global issues: Lessons learned (pp. 106–150). Washington, D.C.: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woods, N. (2003). The United States and the International Financial Institutions: Power and influence within the World Bank and the IMF. In R. Foot, S. N. MacFarlane, & M. Mastanduno (Eds.), US hegemony and international organizations: the United States and multilateral institutions (pp. 92–114). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. Annual Reports. Washington, D.C., various years.

  • World Bank. World Development Indicators. Washington, D.C., various years.

  • World Bank (2002a). Global Development Finance 2002, Volume I: Analysis and Summary Tables. Washington, D.C.

  • World Bank (2002b). Global Development Finance 2002, Volume II: Country Tables. Washington, D.C.

  • World Bank (2006). World Bank Approves US$37 Billion For Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative. World Bank Press Release no. 2006/327/PREM, 28 March 2006.

  • World Bank, & IMF. (1999). The HIPC Initiative: Delivering Debt Relief to Poor Countries, February 1999.

  • Wüstenhagen, A. (2003). Die Vereinten Nationen und der internationale Terrorismus—Versuch einer Chronologie. In S. von Schorlemer (Ed.), Praxishandbuch UNO: die Vereinten Nationen im Lichte globaler Herausforderungen (pp. 101–144). Berlin Heidelberg New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

For most helpful comments I would like to thank the anonymous reviewers of the RIO.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sieglinde Gstöhl.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gstöhl, S. Governance through government networks: The G8 and international organizations. Rev Int Org 2, 1–37 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-006-9004-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-006-9004-8

Keywords

JEL Codes

Navigation