Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Establishment creation and destruction across business density cycles: US evidence

  • Published:
International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates how business establishment entry and exit are affected by cycles in business density. We assess how entry/exit behave when markets over and under shoot a dynamic equilibrium number of businesses and whether these effects differ between manufacturing and service industries. Overall, we find persistent cycles where the actual number of business establishments is typically not equal to the dynamic equilibrium number even though it gravitates towards it. We uncover a systematic pattern which indicates that in disequilibrium entry is dis-equilibrating while closure is equilibrating. For example, the entry rate plays a dis-equilibrating role by accelerating in an overshoot, however as exits accelerate even faster in an overshoot they help move the industry towards an equilibrium. Overall, the results indicate that entrepreneurs and corporations operate with a herd instinct thereby increasing establishments in a cyclical business density over shoot and decreasing them in an under shoot. In terms of economic policy, the results question whether government policy aimed at promoting business creation and expansion ought to have a counter business density cyclical dimension. In other words, should business start-up and growth be promoted more strongly in business density under shoots than over shoots?

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For an overview, see Audretsch et al. (2001); Martin (2002), and Tirole (1988).

  2. In essence, the alternative (which is not an option from our dataset) using data on the number of businesses has the weakness that single and multi establishment firms are counted as the same which is highly questionable in an analysis attempting to establish long term equilibrium relationships. By contrast, establishment/plant data (especially having controlled for minimum efficient scale) provides a more reliable measure of business supply capacity which would be expected to have some long term equilibrium relationships with measures of market size/capacity.

  3. See definition at http://www.census.gov/epcd/susb/introusb.htm#definitions

  4. Another explanation could be that because manufacturing establishments have longer gestation periods, they may be less responsive to yearly changes in GVA.

References

  • Audretsch, D. B. (2002). The dynamic role of small firms: evidence from the US. Small Business Economics, 18, 13–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., Baumol, W. B., & Burke, A. E. (2001). Competition policy in dynamic markets. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19, 613–634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau, D. M. (1987). A time series analysis of self-employment in the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 95, 445–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burke, A. E., van Stel, A., & Thurik, R. (2010). Blue Ocean vs. Five Forces. Harvard Business Review, May, 28.

  • Carree, M., & Thurik, R. (1994). The dynamics of entry, exit and profitability: an error correction approach for the retail industry. Small Business Economics, 6, 107–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P., & Stiglitz, J. (1980). Industrial structure and the nature of innovative activity. Economics Journal, 90, 266–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Day, G. S. (1997). Strategies for surviving a shakeout. Harvard Business Review, 75(2), 92–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1982). Barriers to entry. American Economic Review, 72(1), 47–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunne, T., Roberts, M. J., & Samuelson, L. (1988). Patterns of firm entry and exit in US manufacturing industries. RAND Journal of Economics, 19(4), 495–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, B. C., & Lipsey, R. G. (1980). Exit barriers are entry barriers: the durability of capital as a barrier to entry. Bell Journal of Economics, 11(2), 721–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953). Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geroski, P. A. (1995). What do we know about entry? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 450–456.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geroski, P. A. (2001). Exploring the niche overlaps between organizational ecology and industrial economic. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(2), 507–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (Ed.). (1984). R & D, patents and productivity. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Highfield, R., & Smiley, R. (1987). New business starts and economic activity; an empirical investigation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5, 51–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1962). Entry, Gibrat’s Law, innovation and the growth of firms. American Economic Review, 52(5), 1023–1051.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan and Company (reprinted in 1920).

  • Martin, S. (2002). Advanced industrial economics (2nd ed.). Malden: Blackwell Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orr, D. (1974). The determinants of entry: a study of the Canadian manufacturing industries. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 56, 58–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pakes, A., & Schankerman, M. (1984). An exploration into the determinants of research intensity. In Z. Griliches (Ed.), R & D, patents and productivity. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. (1996). A time series model of self-employment under uncertainty. Economica, 63, 459–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reynolds, P. (1994). Autonomous firm dynamics and economic growth in the United States, 1986–1990. Regional Studies, 28(4), 429–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson, M. T., & Wren, C. (1999). Marginal and average tax rates and the incentive for self-employment. Southern Economic Journal, 65, 757–773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee, R. (1981). Economies of scale and barriers to entry. Journal of Political Economy, 89(6), 1228–1238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schuetze, H. J. (2000). Taxes, economic conditions and recent trends in male self-employment: a Canada-US comparison. Labour Economics, 7, 507–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business cycles. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York, NY: Harper (reprinted in 1975).

  • Shapiro, D., & Khemani, R. S. (1987). The determinants of entry and exit reconsidered. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5, 15–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegfried, J. J. & Evans, L. B. (1994). Empirical studies of entry and exit: a survey of the evidences. Review of Industrial Organization, 9, 121–155.

  • Small Business Administration. (2003). Small Serial Innovators: The small firm contribution to technical change. SBA Study commissioned under contract number SBAHQ-01-C-0149

  • Smith, A. (1776). Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Chicago, IL, University of Chicago Press (reprinted in 1976).

  • Storey, D. J. (1991). The birth of new firms – does unemployment matter? A review of the evidence. Small Business Economics, 3(3), 167–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1988). The theory of industrial organization. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful for comments by referees and participants at various seminar presentations of the research, which have helped to improve the paper. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrew Burke.

Appendix: Description of variables and data sources

Appendix: Description of variables and data sources

Establishments (N), establishment births (E), and establishment deaths (F)

According to Statistics of US Businesses (SUSB) “an establishment is a single physical location at which business is conducted or services or industrial operations are performed”. These range in size from 1 to 4 employees to 500+ employees, and are classified according to the 4-digit NAICS classification system. Data on these have been obtained from the website of US Small Business Administration (SBA) Office of Advocacy. We use the log of N, E and F for all analyses.

Value added to total US GVA by industry sectors

Gross value added (GVA) is equal to an industry’s annual gross output minus its intermediate input. This data is obtained from Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). With the exception of retail and wholesale industry which is aggregated at the two digit NAICS level, value added for other industries is available at the three digit industry level. We convert the nominal GVA to real values using the GDP deflator for the year 2000 as the base and use its log form in the analysis.

R & D expenditure

Research and Development (R & D) expenditure is calculated as a percentage of total industry sales based on the 3-digit NAICS classification for each year of the analysis. This data is also obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA).

Small firm share of patents

The Small Business Administration (2003, Table 6, p. 17) reports the small firm share of patenting technology by technology areas which are broadly aligned with the NAICS/SIC industry classification. We use the data from this table to create a variable capturing the percentage share of patenting by small businesses in different industries.

Minimum efficient scale

We measure the minimum efficient scale requirement in each of the four-digit industries, as the average size (in terms of employees) of the largest plants accounting for 50 % of the industry employment.

Income tax rate

This is the average annual income tax rate on personal income. Data on this variable has been obtained from the tax statistics site of the US Internal Revenue Service website.

Unemployment rate

This is the annual unemployment rate for the US. Data on this variable has been obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor.

Lagged residuals

These are the lagged residuals ε it-1 from the regression of N*. These capture the deviation of actual from sustainable level of business establishments in the previous period.

Overshoots and undershoots

An over shoot indicator of ε it-1 is created by placing a value of zero (where the value of ε it-1 is negative), and vice versa for an under shoot measure.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Burke, A., Shaukat, A. Establishment creation and destruction across business density cycles: US evidence. Int Entrep Manag J 11, 377–392 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11365-014-0337-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11365-014-0337-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation