Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Unlocking the carbon emission efficiency improvement path of technological innovation: a perspective on industrial restructuring and R&D element flows

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Environmental Science and Pollution Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Technological innovation is regarded as an important means to improve carbon efficiency. However, there is no consensus on this view. Meanwhile, few studies have considered how technological innovation affects carbon efficiency. To this end, this study investigates the influencing mechanism and effects of technological innovation on carbon emission efficiency from the perspectives of industrial restructuring and R&D element flow. It establishes the influencing and mechanism model and then deeply studies the impact and paths of technological innovation on carbon emission efficiency, using panel data from 30 provinces in 1999–2020. Results show that (1) technological innovation improves carbon emission efficiency. (2) Regional differences in the impact effects of technological innovation are evident, with a greater contribution to carbon emission efficiency in eastern region. (3) Innovation improves carbon efficiency through two paths: advanced industrial structure and industrial structure rationalization. (4) The moderating effect demonstrates that the technological innovation’s influence is gradually enhanced with the interregional mobility of R&D personnel and capital. Hence, decision-makers should correctly guide the orderly flow of R&D factors and further improve the carbon emission reduction effect by increasing innovation support and helping optimize the industrial structure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

The datasets used during the current study are available from the author on reasonable request.

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Shimei Weng: conceptualization, data curation, and writing, reviewing and editing. Weiliang Tao: writing, review and editing, software, and investigation. Yuling Lu: software; resources; investigation; writing, original draft preparation; writing, review and editing; and validation.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yuling Lu.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval

Not applicable.

Consent to participate

Not applicable.

Consent for publication

Not applicable.

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Responsible Editor: Ilhan Ozturk

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix. The theoretical derivation

Appendix. The theoretical derivation

This paper draws on the research ideas of Tang and Li (2021) to construct a production model of endogenous innovation capability. Assuming that technological innovation is jointly determined by human capital, R&D capital and production technology input, and the output model of endogenous innovation capability can be obtained as follows:

$$Y(X,T)=A{e}^{\alpha t}{X}^{\beta }{T}^{\lambda }(h,r,i)$$
(1)

where Y is total output; A represents the production condition (exogenous constant value); α is exogenous technological progress; X denotes factor input, which is composed of capital (K) and labor (L); β is factor elasticity; T(h,r,i) represents endogenous technological innovation; and λ is the elasticity of innovation output.

Improving innovation capability needs to increase transformation of innovation intensity and innovation input. Assuming that \(T=\phi \times I\) is satisfied between technological innovation and innovation intensity, where ϕ denotes the coefficient of transformation of innovation input into actual innovation capability and I represents innovation intensity. Therefore, the total output is as follows:

$$Y(X,T)=A{e}^{\alpha t}{X}^{\beta }{(\phi \times I)}^{\lambda }$$
(2)

It is further assumed that in the production process, the actual output is composed of high value-added products produced by advanced industrial sectors and low value-added products produced by ordinary industrial sectors, and the actual output is Y1 and Y0, respectively. In general, advanced industry sectors tend to have higher innovation intensity to produce high value-added products, while that of ordinary industry sectors is lower than average. Therefore, we assume that the conversion coefficient and output elasticity of innovation input are the largest in the advanced industry sector and the smallest in the general industry sector, with ϕ and λ satisfying \(0<{\phi }_{0}<\phi <{\phi }_{1}<1\) and \(0<{\lambda }_{0}<\lambda <{\lambda }_{1}<1\).

The ultimate purpose of industrial upgrading or optimization is to increase the added value of existing economic products. Accordingly, the ratio of the output of advanced industrial sectors to the total output is used to measure the industrial upgrading:

$$IU={Y}_{1}/Y=\frac{{A}_{1}}{A}{e}^{\alpha t}{\left(\frac{{X}_{1}}{X}\right)}^{\beta }\frac{{\phi }_{1}^{{\lambda }_{1}}}{{\phi }^{\lambda }}{I}^{{\lambda }_{1}-\lambda }$$
(3)

where X1 and X0 represent the factor input of advanced and ordinary industrial sectors, respectively, the total factor input X = X1 + X0, and the corresponding factor prices of the two sectors are p1 and p0, respectively. In actual production, advanced industrial sectors are often willing to pay higher prices to gain competitive advantages, that is, p1 > p0. In addition, when the factor market achieves long-run equilibrium, p1 X1 = p0 X0. Therefore, industrial optimization can be further summarized as follows:

$$IU={Y}_{1}/Y=\frac{{A}_{1}}{A}{e}^{\alpha t}{\left(\frac{{p}_{1}}{{p}_{1}+{p}_{0}}\right)}^{\beta }\frac{{\phi }_{1}^{{\lambda }_{1}}}{{\phi }^{\lambda }}{I}^{{\lambda }_{1}-\lambda }$$
(4)

Taking the partial derivative of Eq. (4), we get Eq. (5):

$$\frac{\partial IU}{\partial I}=\frac{{A}_{1}}{A}{e}^{\alpha t}{\left(\frac{{p}_{1}}{{p}_{1}+{p}_{0}}\right)}^{\beta }\frac{{\phi }_{1}^{{\lambda }_{1}}}{{\phi }^{\lambda }}\left({\lambda }_{1}-\lambda \right){I}^{{\lambda }_{1}-\lambda -1}>0$$
(5)

Therefore, technological innovation can significantly promote advanced industrial structure.

The rationalization of industrial structure pursues the coordination ability and correlation level between industries, which is mostly measured by the their index. Considering the relatively low output and employment share of the primary industry in China, and to simplify the analysis, we construct the deviation index ID of the industrial structure, which includes the advanced industry sector (the tertiary industry) and the ordinary industry sector (the secondary industry). A larger ID indicates a lower level of industrial structure rationalization:

$$ID=\frac{{Y}_{0}}{Y}{\text{ln}}\left(\frac{{Y}_{0}/Y}{{L}_{0}/L}\right)+\frac{{Y}_{1}}{Y}{\text{ln}}\left(\frac{{Y}_{1}/Y}{{L}_{1}/L}\right)$$
(6)

where L1 and L0 are the number of laborers in advanced and ordinary industry sectors, respectively. We further split ID into M and N, and take partial derivatives of Eqs. (7) and (8):

$$M=\frac{{Y}_{0}}{Y}{\text{ln}}\left(\frac{{Y}_{0}/Y}{{L}_{0}/L}\right)=\left(1-\frac{{Y}_{1}}{Y}\right)\left[{\text{ln}}\left(1-\frac{{Y}_{1}}{Y}\right)-{\text{ln}}\left(1-\frac{{L}_{1}}{L}\right)\right]$$
(7)
$$N=\frac{{Y}_{1}}{Y}{\text{ln}}\left(\frac{{Y}_{1}/Y}{{L}_{1}/L}\right)=\frac{{Y}_{1}}{Y}\left[{\text{ln}}\frac{{Y}_{1}}{Y}-{\text{ln}}\frac{{L}_{1}}{L}\right]$$
(8)
$$\frac{\partial M}{\partial I}=-\frac{{A}_{1}}{A}{e}^{\alpha t}{\left(\frac{{p}_{1}}{{p}_{1}+{p}_{0}}\right)}^{\beta }\frac{{\phi }_{1}^{{\lambda }_{1}}}{{\phi }^{\lambda }}\left({\lambda }_{1}-\lambda \right){I}^{{\lambda }_{1}-\lambda -1}\left[{\text{ln}}\left(1-\frac{{Y}_{1}}{Y}\right)+1-{\text{ln}}\left(1-\frac{{L}_{1}}{L}\right)\right]$$
(9)
$$\frac{\partial N}{\partial I}=\frac{{A}_{1}}{A}{e}^{\alpha t}{\left(\frac{{p}_{1}}{{p}_{1}+{p}_{0}}\right)}^{\beta }\frac{{\phi }_{1}^{{\lambda }_{1}}}{{\phi }^{\lambda }}\left({\lambda }_{1}-\lambda \right){I}^{{\lambda }_{1}-\lambda -1}\left[{\text{ln}}\frac{{Y}_{1}}{Y}+1-{\text{ln}}\frac{{L}_{1}}{L}\right]$$
(10)

Thus, we can obtain the partial derivative of industrial structure deviation degree on technological innovation:

$$\begin{array}{c}\frac{\partial ID}{\partial I}=\frac{{A}_{1}}{A}{e}^{\alpha t}{\left(\frac{{p}_{1}}{{p}_{1}+{p}_{0}}\right)}^{\beta }\frac{{\phi }_{1}^{{\lambda }_{1}}}{{\phi }^{\lambda }}\left({\lambda }_{1}-\lambda \right){I}^{{\lambda }_{1}-\lambda -1}\left[{\text{ln}}\frac{{Y}_{1}}{{Y}_{0}}-{\text{ln}}\frac{{L}_{1}}{{L}_{0}}\right]\\ =\frac{{A}_{1}}{A}{e}^{\alpha t}{\left(\frac{{p}_{1}}{{p}_{1}+{p}_{0}}\right)}^{\beta }\frac{{\phi }_{1}^{{\lambda }_{1}}}{{\phi }^{\lambda }}\left({\lambda }_{1}-\lambda \right){I}^{{\lambda }_{1}-\lambda -1}ln\frac{L{P}_{1}}{L{P}_{0}}\end{array}$$
(11)

where LP1 and LP0 denote the labor productivity of advanced and ordinary industrial sectors, respectively. Considering that the labor productivity of China’s secondary industry is higher than that of the tertiary industry (Zhang et al. 2019), \(\partial ID/\partial I<0\). According to this, technological innovation can promote industrial structure rationalization.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Weng, S., Tao, W. & Lu, Y. Unlocking the carbon emission efficiency improvement path of technological innovation: a perspective on industrial restructuring and R&D element flows. Environ Sci Pollut Res 31, 21189–21207 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-024-32510-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-024-32510-y

Keywords

Navigation