Skip to main content
Log in

The Impact of Institutional Path Dependence on Water Market Efficiency in Victoria, Australia

  • Published:
Water Resources Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Water governance in Australia’s irrigation sector has undergone substantial change over the last three decades. In part, this change has been the result of a shift in intellectual thinking regarding the pricing and allocation of irrigation water with a move away from primary reliance on government to undertake these activities and a greater dependence on markets. Institutional change will be impacted on by the existence of institutional path dependence created by previous frameworks. Path dependence arises because actors are unable to predict the exact outcome of decisions made at different junctures in time. Individual decisions may be temporally remote but will impact the subsequent path of change as a result of lock-in. In turn, institutional path dependence may create some rigidity within new institutional arrangements. Evidence of current trading restrictions on Victorian water markets illustrates this outcome. These restrictions may not be permanent, but in the short-run they have limited, to some extent, the gains accruing from water trading.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Markets require good governance but this does not always come in the form of ‘government’ typical of the modern nation state. For example, tribal villages have governance power vested in a chief or group of elders who are responsible for creating the rules of the game when it comes to resource ownership and exploitation. Further, in California during the 1849 gold rush, in the absence of government, miners themselves defined and enforced resource access and use rules thereby providing effective governance for market stability (Libecap 2007; Umbeck 1981).

  2. Throughout the remainder of the paper the term ‘efficiency’ will refer exclusively to economic efficiency unless otherwise clarified in the text.

  3. An impure public good has features of both private and public goods in that they are rival but non-excludable. Refer to section three for more detail.

  4. In-stream salinity is the result of saline groundwater recharge and run-off from saline irrigation areas. Run-off is the result of saline groundwater being discharged at the soil surface and concentrated by evaporation. This damages soils on-site and the salt eventually drains into river systems (Beresford et al. 2004).

  5. Section four states, “The right to use all of the water at any time in any river stream watercourse lake lagoon swamp or marsh shall for the purposes of this Act in every case be deemed to be vested in the Crown…”

  6. National defence is a good example because an army is unable to prevent supplying defence to citizens that have not paid their taxes. Further, because defence is non-rival the amount supplied to one individual does not reduce the amount available for others.

  7. Non-rivalry may exist only at low levels of use so that these resources become increasingly rival as user numbers rise because of congestion. For example, members of a tennis club are permitted to use available court space whenever they please but the amount of court space is limited so that if all members want to practice at the same time congestion problems arise. Congestion leads to increasing rivalry over available court space.

  8. A vast literature deals with the rise and fall of commons arrangements for example: Alston et al. 2009, 2011; Demsetz 1967; Dennen 1976; Hardin 1968; Libecap 2007; Wade 1988.

  9. Competition will be characterised by a race because non-excludability means one actor cannot prevent other actors from utilising the resource. In turn, actors are unable to place exclusive claim on the rental stream accruing from resource exploitation in future periods. This uncertainty creates incentives that encourage a race by all actors to harvest as much of the good as possible in period one. In order to maximise harvesting efforts increased capital investment is required for example in the case of a fishery, bigger boats and more sophisticated harvesting equipment. The result is the tragedy of the commons (Hardin 1968).

  10. The building of a vast storage network and extensive river regulation ensured farmers had guaranteed water supply even during prolonged drought. In an ordinary rainfall year farmers were guaranteed 100% of their water rights. In drought years supply would decrease to 70%. Guaranteed supplies created income stability for farmers so they were partially protected from boom-bust cycles caused by Australia’s variable climate. Farmers’ incomes were also kept stable via extensive price regulation of agricultural goods, broadly referred to as price stabilisation schemes. For further details refer to McKay (1968).

  11. The VSRWSC was the first statutory corporation of its kind in the world. Section 28 of the 1905 Water Act stated the Commission was to be a body corporate and was to have, “perpetual succession and a common seal and be capable in law of suing and being sued.”

  12. Marginal cost pricing requires each additional unit of a product to be priced at the cost of that extra unit. Pricing below marginal cost means a business will charge a price for the additional unit that does not allow them to recoup production costs. No profit maximising firm in a competitive industry would price below marginal cost.

  13. It was possible to trade water on the New South Wales and Victorian gold fields during the 1850s and 1860s with the adoption of prior appropriation. For details refer to Harris (2010).

  14. This 4% limit remains in place as at July 1, 2011, refer to the Victorian Water Register (2011) website: http://waterregister.vic.gov.au/Public/Reports/WaterTradeFourPercent.aspx <Accessed July 5, 2011 > .

References

  • Acemoglu D (2006) Modelling inefficient institutions. NBER Working Paper 11940 National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA (2000) Why did the West extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. Q J Econ 115:1167–1199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2001) The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. Am Econ Rev 91:1369–1401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2002) Reversal of fortune: geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. Q J Econ 117:1231–1294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alston L, Harris E, Mueller B (2009) De Facto and De Jure Property Rights: land settlement and land onflict on the Australian, Brazilian and U.S. frontiers. NBER Working Paper 15264 National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

  • Alston L, Harris E, Mueller B (2011) Property rights, land settlement and land conflict on frontiers: evidence from Australia, Brazil and the US. In: Ayotte K, Smith H E (eds) Research handbook on the economics of property law Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 9–34

  • Beresford Q, Beckle H, Phillips H, Mulcock J (2004) The salinity crisis: landscapes, communities, and politics. University of Western Australia Press, Perth

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjornlund H (2002) Signs of maturity in Australian water markets. NZ Prop J July: 31–46

  • Bjornlund H, McKay J (2000) Do water markets promote socially equitable reallocation of water? A case study of a rural water market in Victoria, Australia. Rivers 7:139–152

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan D (2006) Water policy reform in Australia: lessons from the Victorian seasonal water market. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 50:403–423

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks R, Harris E (2008) Efficiency gains from water markets: empirical analysis from Watermove. Agr Water Manag 95:391–399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Candee H (1989) The broken promise of reclamation reform. Hastings Law J 40:657–686

    Google Scholar 

  • Challen R (2000) Institutions, transaction costs, and environmental policy: institutional reform for water resources. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Crase L, O’Reilly L, Dollery B (2000) Water markets as a vehicle for water reform: the case of New South Wales. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 44:299–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cunningham RB, Morton R (1983) A statistical method for the estimation of trend in salinity in the River Murray. Aust J Soil Res 21:123–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • David PA (1985) Clio and the economics of QWERTY. Am Econ Rev 75:332–337

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz H (1967) Towards a theory of property rights. Am Econ Rev 57:347–359

    Google Scholar 

  • Dennen RT (1976) Cattlemen’s associations and property rights in the American West. Explor Econ Hist 13:423–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs A (1957) An economic theory of democracy. Harper and Brothers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Engerman SL, Sokoloff KL (2003) Institutional and non-institutional explanations of economic differences. NBER Working Paper 9989 National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

  • Engerman SL, Sokoloff KL (2005) Colonialism, inequality, and long-Run paths of development. NBER Working Paper 11057 National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

  • Goldberg VP (1974) Institutional change and the quasi-Invisible hand. J Law Econ 17:461–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grief A (1998) Historical and comparative institutional analysis. Am Econ Rev 88:80–84

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin R (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Sci 162:1243–1248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris E (2007) Historical regulation of Victoria’s water sector: a case of government failure? Aust J Agric Resour Econ 51:343–352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris E (2008) Colonialism and Long-run Growth in Australia: an examination of institutional change in Victoria’s water sector during the nineteenth century. Aust Econ Hist Rev 48:266–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris E (2010) Scarcity and the evolution of water rights in the nineteenth century: the role of climate and asset type. Discussion Paper 45/10 Monash University, Department of Economics, Monash University

  • Harris E (2011) Does franchise extension reduce short-run economic growth? Evidence from New South Wales, 1862–1882. International Society for New Institutional Economists Annual Conference, Stanford June 16–18

  • Heaney A, Dwyer G, Beare S, Peterson D, Pechy L (2006) Third-Party effects of water trading and potential policy responses. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 50:277–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanazawa M (1993) Pricing subsidies and economic efficiency: the U.S. Bureau of Reclamation. J Law Econ 36:205–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Libecap GD (2007) The assignment of property rights on the Western frontier: lessons for contemporary environmental and resource Policy. J Econ Hist 67:257–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKay DH (1968) Stabilisation in Australian agriculture. Aust J Agric Econ 9:33–52

    Google Scholar 

  • McKay J (2005) Water institutional reforms in Australia. Water Policy 7:35–52

    Google Scholar 

  • National Water Commission (2010) Impacts of water trading in the southern Murray-Darling Basin: an economic, social, and environmental assessment. Government Printer, Canberra

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1971) Institutional change and economic growth. J Econ Hist 31:118–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1981) Structure and change in economic history. W W Norton and Co, London

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Melbourne

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1994) Economic performance through time. Am Econ Rev 84:359–368

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1965) The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press, Massachusetts

  • Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pakula BAE (2004) Irrigation and river salinity in Sunraysia: an economic investigations of an environmental problem. Working Paper Department of Primary Industry, Victoria

  • Pigram JJ (1993) Property rights and water markets in Australia: an evolutionary process toward institutional reform. Water Resour Res 29:1313–1319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Productivity Commission (2006) Rural water use and the environment: the role of market mechanisms. Productivity Commission, Canberra

    Google Scholar 

  • Qureshi M, Shi T, Qureshi S, Proctor W (2009) Removing barriers to facilitate efficient water markets in the Murray-Darling Basin of Australia. Agr Water Manag 96:1641–1651

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qureshi M, Schwabe K, Connor J, Kirby M (2010) Environmental water incentive policy and return flows. Water Resour Res 46 W04517. doi: 10.1029/2008WR007445

  • Smith HE (2000) Semicommon property rights and scattering in the open fields. J Leg Stud 24:131–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1971) The theory of economic regulation. Bell J Econ 3:3–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1974) Free riders and collective action: an appendix to theories of economic regulation. Bell J Econ Manag Sci 5:359–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Umbeck JR (1981) A theory of property rights with application to the California gold rush. Iowa State Press, Ames

    Google Scholar 

  • Victorian Auditor General (2004) Special review of the water sector. Government Printer, Melbourne

    Google Scholar 

  • Victorian State Rivers and Water Supply Commission (1906/07-1983/84) Annual Report Votes and Proceedings of the Legislative Assembly. Government Printer, Melbourne

  • Victorian Water Register (2011) http://waterregister.vic.gov.au/Public/Reports/WaterTradeFourPercent.aspx Accessed July 5 2011

  • Wade R (1988) Village republics: economic conditions for collective action in southern India. Cambridge University Press, Sydney

    Google Scholar 

  • Young M, McColl J C (2003) Robust reform: implementing robust institutional arrangements to achieve efficient water use in Australia. CSIRO Land and Water

  • Young M, MacDonald D, Stringer R, and Bjornlund H (2000) Inter-state water trading: a two year review. CSIRO Land and Water

Download references

Acknowledgments

I extend many thanks to Robert Brooks, the Editors, and two anonymous referees for valuable feedback on previous drafts. All remaining errors are my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Edwyna Harris.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Harris, E. The Impact of Institutional Path Dependence on Water Market Efficiency in Victoria, Australia. Water Resour Manage 25, 4069–4080 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11269-011-9884-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11269-011-9884-0

Keywords

Navigation