Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Women and poverty: insights from individual consumption in Albania

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies how a society with traditional gender norms and competitive marriage market conditions may favor unequal distribution of resources within households and a consequent increase in female poverty. We propose a method to estimate individual consumption from household expenditure data. After estimating individual consumption, we apply a fuzzy approach for poverty analysis. Compared to standard poverty measures, the approach is less sensitive to changes in the distribution of consumption around the poverty line, generated when accounting for unequal distribution of household resources. The approach, applied to the analysis of individual poverty in Albania, revealed considerable intrahousehold inequality that specifically affects women and is correlated with imbalances in the sex ratio induced by past migrations. This leads to an expected general increase in poverty rates, mainly driven by a previously unperceived issue, female poverty, which emerges as an aspect of concern to consider in future anti-poverty policies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This method has been successfully implemented in different economic fields; for instance to monitor the effects of marital disruption on well-being (Aassve et al. 2007), to measure the multidimensional education mismatch (Betti et al. 2011), and to study multidimensional measures of quality of life (Betti et al. 2016). The positive results achieved by the fuzzy set approach in areas other than poverty demonstrate its wide applicability and robustness.

  2. The Albanian Institute of Statistics (INSTAT) reports that in 2002, 25.2% of Albanians were living in absolute poverty, which reduced to 17.9% in 2005 and 12.5% in 2008. The recent global financial crisis has interrupted the positive trend with the poverty rate increasing to 14.3% in 2012. For 2002 and 2005, Mastromarco et al. (2014) found that living in rural and mountain areas, being female, poorly educated and with a large family increased the probability of suffering from deprivation. Additionally, Mangiavacchi and Verme (2013) provided evidence that existing income support programs had a weak targeting capacity and a non-significant impact on different household outcomes in the same period.

  3. To deal with households of size larger than 3 with different composition, we propose to “rescale” these households as if they had only three members. Accordingly, qki is expenditure of member category k divided by the number of members in category k, \(y_i = \mathop {\sum}\nolimits_k q_{ki} + Kc_{ki}\), and K = 2,3 is the number of household member categories.

  4. The choice of a proper set of correction factors is crucial for identifying individual consumption and is discussed in Section 2.3.

  5. The proposed method comes with one caveat. At present, the empirical estimation of intrahousehold inequality does not account for economies of scale in consumption. This, however, is not an issue for the present study because the official poverty measurement strategy of the Albanian Statistical Institute (INSTAT), supported by the World Bank, is based on per-capita consumption, which likewise does not account for economies of scale.

  6. A similar procedure has been applied by Dunbar et al. (2013) within a collective consumption framework on a sample of couples with children in Malawi. Differences with our approach are substantial. First, we proposed a reduced form approach that is compatible with but not restricted to collective models. Second, the authors make a different use of assignable consumption: they propose a system of Engel curves for assignable goods only, one good for each member category k, which depends of preferences and resource share of that member only. Third, they achieve identification of the distribution of resources by imposing restrictions on preferences rather then using distribution factors (the equivalent of our correction factors in the collective literature).

  7. The traditional approach is a special case of the fuzzy approach, where the membership function may be seen as μ(yl) = 1 if yl < z, μ(yl) = 0 if yl ≥ z where yl is consumption expenditure of individual l and z is the poverty line. For a systematic comparison of the theory of fuzzy sets with other approaches to poverty analysis, especially in a multidimensional framework, see Deutsch and Silber (2005).

  8. The aggregate FM indicator has a straightforward economic interpretation as it can be expressed in terms of generalized Gini measures Gα, i.e., \({\mathrm{FM}} = \frac{{\alpha + G_\alpha }}{{\alpha \left( {\alpha + 1} \right)}} = {\mathrm{HCR}}\). So the proposed FM indicator is a generalized inequality measure where the weight given to the poorer tail of the distribution (α) is such that the FM value equals the HCR.

  9. This choice is motivated by the definition of the assignable consumption variable as expenditure on children’s clothing and footwear, used to compute σki in Eq. (2), recorded for children under 15 years.

  10. Had we been willing to avoid this household scaling procedure, we would have had to estimate a different Engel curve system for each possible combination of household composition, each on its own subsample, leading to estimation difficulties for all those household compositions with insufficient sample size (namely almost all of them).

  11. The F-statistics of the exclusion restrictions of the first stage (asset index and household income) are 159.93 for model (i) and 152.62 for model (ii), well beyond the critical values for a maximum relative bias of 5% compared to OLS, i.e., 20.25 (Stock and Yogo 2005).

  12. WiHo stands for Work in Household, namely the amount of work performed in the household by each member to the exclusive benefit of the other member.

  13. The distribution of the predicted and estimated mk(z) functions were very similar, suggesting that excluding certain families from the estimation of the collective Engel curve system did not generate significant sample selection bias in the estimation of intrahousehold distribution of resources. Figures and statistics are available on request.

  14. This value was computed by the Cost of Basic Needs method. It is therefore an absolute poverty line, and the official consumption variable used for poverty measurement in subsequent years was deflated regionally.

  15. Indeed, this measure has exactly the same population mean as per-capita consumption, but of course, and this is the value added by accounting for intrahousehold inequality, the dispersion is not the same.

References

  • Aassve, A., Betti, G., Mazzuco, S., & Mencarini, L. (2007). Marital disruption and economic well-being: a comparative analysis. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society), 170(3), 781–799.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Giuliano, P., & Nunn, N. (2013). On the origins of gender roles: women and the plough. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(2), 469–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almås, I., Armand, A., Attanasio, O., & Carneiro, P. (2018). Measuring and changing control: women’s empowerment and targeted transfers. Economic Journal, 128, 609–639.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G., Pittau, M. G., & Zelli, R. (2014). Poverty status probability: a new approach to measuring poverty and the progress of the poor. The Journal of Economic Inequality, 12(4), 469–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banks, J., Blundell, R., & Lewbel, A. (1997). Quadratic Engel curves and consumer demand. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(4), 527–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. The Economic Journal, 75(299), 493–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1973). A theory of marriage: part I. Journal of Political Economy, 81(4), 813–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1974). A theory of social interactions. Journal of political economy, 82(6), 1063–1093.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1981). A Treatise on the Family. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.

  • Betti, G., D’Agostino, A., & Neri, L. (2011). Educational mismatch of graduates: a multidimensional and fuzzy indicator. Social Indicators Research, 103(3), 465–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Betti, G., Soldi, R., & Talev, I. (2016). Fuzzy multidimensional indicators of quality of life: the empirical case of Macedonia. Social Indicators Research, 127(1), 39–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Betti, G., & Verma, V. (2008). Fuzzy measures of the incidence of relative poverty and deprivation: a multi-dimensional perspective. Statistical Methods and Applications, 17(2), 225–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonke, J. (2015). Pooling of income and sharing of consumption within households. Review of Economics of the Household, 13(1), 73–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M., Bourguignon, F. Chiappori, P., & Lechene V. (1994). Income and outcomes: a structural model of intrahousehold allocation. Journal of Political Economy, 102(6), 1067–1096.

  • Cheli, B., & Betti, G. (1999). Totally fuzzy and relative measures of poverty dynamics in an italian pseudo panel. Metron, 57, 83–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheli, B., & Lemmi, A. (1995). A totally fuzzy and relative approach to the multidimensional analysis of poverty. Economic Notes, 24, 115–134.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cuesta, J. (2006). The distributive consequences of machismo: a simulation analysis of intra-household discrimination. Journal of International Development, 18(8), 1065–1080.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deutsch, J., & Silber, J. (2005). Measuring multidimensional poverty: an empirical comparison of various approaches. Review of Income and Wealth, 51(1), 145–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duflo, E. (2012). Women empowerment and economic development. Journal of Economic Literature, 50(4), 1051–1079.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunbar, G., Lewbel, A., & Pendakur, K. (2013). Children’s resources in collective households: Identification, estimation, and an application to child poverty in Malawi. The American Economic Review, 103(1), 438–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel, E. (1857). Die Productions-und Consumptions-Verhaltnisse des Konigreichs Sachsen’. Bulletin de I’Institut International de Statistique9, 1–54.

  • Farre, L., & Vella, F. (2013). The intergenerational transmission of gender role attitudes and its implications for female labour force participation. Economica, 80(318), 219–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Findlay, J., & Wright, R. E. (1996). Gender, poverty and the intra-household distribution of resources. Review of Income and Wealth, 42(3), 335–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giménez-Nadal, J. I., Mangiavacchi, L., & Piccoli, L. (2019). Keeping inequality at home: The genesis of gender roles in housework. Labour Economics, 58, 52–68.

  • Gimenez-Nadal, J. I., Molina, J. A., & Zhu, Y. (2018). Intergenerational mobility of housework time in the United Kingdom. Review of Economics of the Household, 16, 911–937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gjonca, A., Aassve, A., & Mencarini, L. (2008). Trends and patterns, proximate determinants and policies of fertility change: Albania. Demographic research, 19(11), 261–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H. (2018). Econometric Analysis. 8th Edition NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard, S. (2015a). A consumption theory with competitive markets for work-in-household. In The Marriage Motive: A Price Theory of Marriage (pp. 167–189). Springer, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard, S. (2015b). The marriage motive: a price theory of marriage. Springer, New York.

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, S. (1993). On the economics of marriage: a theory of marriage, labor, and divorce. Westview Press, Boulder.

  • Guilmoto, C. Z., Dudwick, N., Gjonça, A., & Rahm, L. (2018). How Do Demographic Trends Change? The Onset of Birth Masculinization in Albania, Georgia, and Vietnam 1990–2005. Population and Development Review, 44(1), 37–61.

  • Haddad, L., & Kanbur, R. (1990). How serious is the neglect of intra-household inequality? Economic Journal, 100(402), 866–881. September.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • INSTAT (2013). Return migration and reintegration in Albania.

  • INSTAT (2015). Albania: trends in poverty 2002-2005-2008-2012.

  • Lundberg, S., & Pollak, R. A. (1993). Separate spheres bargaining and the marriage market. Journal of political Economy, 101(6), 988–1010.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S. J., Pollak, R. A., & Wales, T. J. (1997). Do husbands and wives pool their resources? evidence from the united kingdom child benefit. Journal of Human resources, 32(3), 463–480.

  • Mangiavacchi, L., Perali, F., & Piccoli, L. (2018). Intrahousehold distribution in migrant-sending families. Journal of Demographic Economics, 84(1), 107–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mangiavacchi, L., & Verme, P. (2013). Minimum income in a transition economy: a pro-poor measure or a poor safety net? Economics of Transition, 21(4), 683–712.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mastromarco, C., Peragine, V., Russo, F., & Serlenga, L. (2014). Poverty, inequality and growth in albania: empirical evidence, 2002-05. Economics of Transition, 22(4), 635–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McElroy, M. B., & Horney M. J. (1981). Nash-bargained household decisions: toward a generalization of the theory of demand. International Economic Review, 22(2), 333–349.

  • Mendola, M., & Carletto, C. (2012). Migration and gender differences in the home labour market: evidence from Albania. Labour Economics, 19(6), 870–880.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menon, M., Perali, F., & Piccoli, L. (2018). Collective consumption: and application to the passive drinking effect. Review of Economics of the Household, 16(1), 143–169. Special Issue: In Honor of Nobel Laureate Angus Deaton: “Consumption, Poverty and Inequality in the Household”.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osberg, L. (2015). The hunger of old women in rural Tanzania: can subjective data improve poverty measurement? Review of Income and Wealth, 61(4), 723–738.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M. (2016). How do sex ratios in China influence marriage decisions and intra-household resource allocation? Review of Economics of the Household, 14(2), 337–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quisumbing, A. R., & Maluccio, J. A. (2003). Resources at marriage and intrahousehold allocation: evidence from Bangladesh, Ethiopia, Indonesia, and South Africa. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 65(3), 283–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J. H., & Yogo, M. (2005). Testing for weak instruments in linear iv regression. Identification and Inference for Econometric Models: Essays in Honor of Thomas Rothenberg, 80, 80–108.

  • Terza, J. V., Basu, A., & Rathouz, P. J. (2008). Two-stage residual inclusion estimation: addressing endogeneity in health econometric modeling. Journal of Health Economics, 27, 531–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vijaya, R. M., Lahoti, R., & Swaminathan, H. (2014). Moving from the household to the individual: multidimensional poverty analysis. World Development, 59, 70–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vullnetari, J. (2012). Women and migration in Albania: a view from the village. International Migration, 50(5), 169–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zadeh, L. A. (1965). Fuzzy sets. Information and Control, 8(3), 338–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are very grateful to the editor Shoshana Grossbard and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions. Lucia Mangiavacchi and Luca Piccoli received financial support from the Spanish Ministry for the Economy and Competitiveness (grant ECO2015-63727-R).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lucia Mangiavacchi.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher’s note: Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Betti, G., Mangiavacchi, L. & Piccoli, L. Women and poverty: insights from individual consumption in Albania. Rev Econ Household 18, 69–91 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-019-09452-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-019-09452-3

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation