Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Time with sons and daughters

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We present a model of parental investment in child quality in which the effectiveness—objectively or as perceived by the parents—of parental childcare depends on the sex of the child. In particular, the time of the same-sex parent is more productive than that of the opposite-sex parent. When parents have equal wages, efficiency considerations dictate that a parent spends more time with a same-sex child than with an opposite-sex child, but parents allocate the same total time to boys and girls, and costs of raising a boy are the same as raising a girl. When wage rates differ, and the mother is the lower-waged parent, it is cheaper to produce child quality of girls than of boys. We show that many of the empirical results in terms of a different time allocation pattern, total amount of time invested in a child, expenditures on child consumption goods, and family size and composition can be explained by this technological difference and the gender wage gap, without relying on parental preferences for girls versus boys. Our analysis is largely diagrammatic.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Indirect evidence for different parental treatment of boys and girls is also provided by studies that find that fathers change their hours worked by more after having a boy than having a girl. See Lundberg and Rose (2002).

  2. Results of higher relative wages for mothers compared to fathers are mixed (Connelly and Kimmel 2009;  Bloemen and Stancanelli 2008).

  3. We use the term "opposite-sex" throughout the paper, rather than "different-sex".

  4. Information taken from http://www.girlguides.ca/who_we_are.

  5. More women are involved in coaching on girls’ teams, but they are still in the minority in their sample.

  6. The explanation that boys and girls need role models is a bit more complicated, because girls may benefit from seeing their mother work and take some leisure for herself. Thus being role models may be a function of how parents spend all their time, not just how they interact or how much time they spend with the child. The fact that maternal employment has a differential impact on sons and daughters suggests that gender role modelling is a very complex phenomenon (Tanaka 2008 provides a brief survey).

  7. See Landes (2009) for the criticism of Toys ’R’ Us (and comments by readers of The Local) and Williams (2010) for a discussion of Shiloh Jolie-Pitt’s haircut and clothing style.

  8. We ignore fertility choices in our formal model, but in the discussion section we mention some implications for fertility decisions arising from our model.

  9. Time with the child yields no direct utility; this is a standard assumption in the literature.

  10. We ignore assets.

  11. Additive separability seems a natural modelling choice as this insures that a child receives quality time even in a single-parent household. But it also captures the idea that in (functional) marriages having both parents spend at least some time in childcare is always superior to having the same amount of time spent with only one parent. See Pollak (2007) for a similar discussion.

  12. Whether this is the result of matching in the marriage market, or of an earlier stage in marriage in which the mother takes some time off from work to recover from child birth and care for the small infant, is left outside the model. If the inequality were reversed, all our results would be reversed as well.

  13. Definition 2 specifies that a reflection will be assumed to be about the 45° ray.

  14. In the working paper version of this paper we hold constant the full income of the household (w h  + w w ) rather than the cost of this quality time for a girl. The approach in this paper yields the same results, and minimizes additional notation.

  15. A recent study on house prices and divorce rates in the US suggests that divorce rates decline when house prices are low because divorce is too costly (Farnham et al. 2011).

  16. See e.g. Parviainen (2003) and Haavio-Mannila (1969).

  17. Different social policies may also influence the differences in the gender wage gaps in these countries. See Datta Gupta et al. (2008).

  18. This is consistent with empirical findings from the US; see Barnett and Baruch (1987) and Harris and Morgan (1991).

  19. Lundberg et al. (1997)’s empirical analysis of the change in how child benefits were transferred to parents in the UK suggests that mothers care more about their children than do fathers. Studies in developing countries (e.g. Hoddinott and Haddad 1995; Chiwaula and Kawula 2008) reach the same conclusion.

  20. However, if spouses have unequal concern for their children and utility is transferable, bargaining power has no impact on child quality and Proposition 1 survives. This is a special case of the point made in a more general setting in Gugl and Leroux (2010).

  21. By optimal we mean utility maximizing on the segment of the linear bc that is contained in the actual bc of parents with a girl.

References

  • Andersson, G., Hank, K., Ronsen, M., & Vikat, A. (2006). Gendering the family composition: Sex preferences for children and childbearing in the Nordic Countries. Demography, 43(2), 255–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baccara, M., Collard-Wexler, A., Felli, L., & Yariv, L. (2010). Gender and racial biases: evidence from child adoption, CESifo Working Paper 2921.

  • Barnett, R. C., & Baruch, G. K. (1987). Determinants of fathers’ participation in family work. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 49(1), 29–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman, J. R., Pollak, R. A., & Taubman, P. (1986). Do parents favor boys?. International Economic Review, 27(1), 33–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloemen, H., & Stancanelli, E. (2008). How do parents allocate time? The effects of wages and income. IZA Discussion Papers 3679, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).

  • Chiwaula, L. S., & Kaluwa, B. M. (2008). Household consumption of infant foods in two low-income districts in Malawi. Journal of International Development, 20(5), 686–697.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, J., & Kimmell, J. (2009). Spousal influences on parents’ non-market time choices. Review of Economics of the Household, 7(4), 361–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, G. B., & Moretti, E. (2008). The demand for sons. Review of Economic Studies, 75(4), 1085–1120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Datta Gupta N., Smith, N., & Verner, M. (2008). PERSPECTIVE ARTICLE: The impact of Nordic countries’ family friendly policies on employment, wages, and children. Review of Economics of the Household, 6, 65–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farnham, M., Schmidt, L., & Sevak, P. (2011). House prices and marital stability. American Economic Review: Paper and Proceedings, 101(3), 615–619.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giuliano, L. (2007). The demand for sons or the Demand for fathers? Understanding the effects of child gender on divorce Rates. University of Miami, Department of Economics wp # 0724.

  • Gugl, E., & Leroux, J. (2010). Share the gain, share the pain?—almost transferable utility, changes in production possibilities, and bargaining solutions, working paper, University of Victoria.

  • Gugl, E., & Welling, L. (2010). The early bird gets the worm? Birth order effects in a dynamic family model. Economic Inquiry, 48(3), 690–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gugl, E., Welling, L., & Wang, T. M. (2011). Efficiency of bargaining models with renegotiation: The role of transferable utility across periods. mimeo: University of Victoria.

  • Haavio-Mannila, E. (1969). The position of Finnish women: Regional and cross-national comparisons. Journal of Marriage and Family, 31(2), 339–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, K. M., & Morgan, S. P. (1991). Fathers, sons, and daughters: Differential paternal involvement in parenting. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 53(3), 531–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoddinott, J., & Haddad, L. (1995) Does female income share influence household expenditure? Evidence from Cote d’Ivoire. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 57, 77–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsen, R., Moller, H., & Engholm, G. (1999). Fertility rates in Denmark in relation to the sexes of preceding children in the family. Human Reproduction, 14(4), 1127–1130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, D. (2009). Toys"R"Us scolded for gender discrimination, The Local, Published: 6 Oct 09 16:26, http://www.thelocal.se/22504/20091006/.

  • Lundberg, S. (2005a). Sons, daughters, and parental behaviour. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 21(3), 340–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S. (2005b). The division of labor by new parents: Does child gender matter?. IZA Discussion Paper 1787.

  • Lundberg, S., Pollak, R. A., & Wales, T. J. (1997). Do husbands and wives pool their resources? Evidence from the United Kingdom child benefit. Journal of Human Resources, 32(3), 463–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S., & Rose, E. (2004). Investments in sons and daughters: Evidence from the consumer expenditure survey. In A. Kalil & T. De Leire (Eds.), Family investments in children resources and behavior that promote success (pp. 163–180). Mahwih: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S., & Rose, E. (2002). The effects of sons and daughters on men’s labor supply and wages. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 251–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Messner, M. A., & Bozada-Deas, S. (2009). Separating the men from the moms: The making of adult gender segregation in youth sports. Gender & Society, 23(1), 49–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olivetti, C., & Petrongolo, B. (2008). Unequal pay or unequal employment? A cross-country analysis of gender gaps. Journal of Labor Economics, 26(4), 621–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parviainen, S. (2003). Recent trends and future prospects in gender equality, eironline: European industrial relations observatory on-line, FI0310202F, published 28-10-2003, http://www.eurofound.europa.eu/eiro/2003/10/feature/fi0310202f.ht.

  • Pollak, R. A. (2007). Allocating time: Individuals’ technologies and household technology, revised May 14/07.

  • Price, J. (2008). Parent-child quality time: Does birth order matter?. Journal of Human Resources, 43(1), 240–265.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka, R. (2008). The gender-asymmetric effect of working mothers on children’s education: Evidence from Japan. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 22(4), 586–640.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, M. E. (2010). Shiloh Jolie-Pitt: Preschool gender warrior: Tabloids foam over the famous tot’s attire, showing just how eager we are to narrowly define sex roles, salon.com, published 4 Mar 10 13:05 ET, http://www.salon.com/life/feature/2010/03/04/shiloh_jolie_pitt_hair_drama.

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the editor of this journal, two anonymous referees, Frances Woolley, and participants in a session at the 2010 annual meetings of the Canadian Economics Association, and in seminars at the University of Victoria, Canada, and the Karl-Franzens University, Graz, Austria for helpful comments. The authors blame all errors on each other.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Linda Welling.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Remark 1

Inspection of the FOC’s from (1) yields

$$ \frac{w_{w}}{w_{h}} =\frac{\partial F^{c}(t_{w},t_{h})/\partial t_{w}}{ \partial F^{c}(t_{w},t_{h})/\partial t_{h}} $$
(16)
$$ w_{j} =\frac{\partial Q(F^{c}(t_{w},t_{h}),x^{c})/\partial F^{c}}{\partial Q(F^{c}(t_{w},t_{h}),x^{c})/\partial x^{c}}\frac{\partial F^{c}(t_{w},t_{h})}{\partial t_{j}},\quad j=w,h $$
(17)

The FOC’s for cost minimization of Q(F(t w t h ), x c) are

$$ \begin{aligned} w_{j}-\lambda ^{c}\frac{\partial Q\left( F^{c}(t_{w},t_{h}),x^{c}\right) }{ \partial F^{c}}\frac{\partial F^{c}(t_{w},t_{h})}{\partial t_{j}} &=0,\quad j=w,h \\ 1-\lambda ^{c}\frac{\partial Q\left( F^{c}(t_{w},t_{h}),x^{c}\right) }{\partial x^{c}} &=0 \end{aligned}$$

Conditions (16)–(17) above can be recovered from these FOCs. Finally, minimizing the cost of t q yields FOCs

$$ w_{j}-\mu \left( \partial F^{c}(t_{w},t_{h})/\partial t_{j}\right) =0,\quad j=w,h $$

Thus condition (16) is necessary for all three problems. \(\square\)

Proof of Lemma 2

Marginal costs\(\square\)

Let \(C\left( w_{ss},w_{os},t_{q}\right) \) be the cost function of quality time. We want to know the change in marginal cost as w ss switches from w w to w h and as w os switches from w h to w w . That is, dw ss  = w h  − w w dw os  = w w  − w h . By the FOC’s of the cost minimization problem, \(\mu =w_{os}/\left( \alpha f^{\prime }\left( t_{os}\right) \right) =w_{ss}/f^{\prime }\left( t_{ss}\right) \) and by the Envelope Theorem, \(\partial C/\partial t_{q}=\mu .\) We want to determine the sign of \(\frac{\partial C}{\partial t_{q}\partial w_{ss}}dw_{ss}+\frac{\partial C}{\partial t_{q}\partial w_{os}}dw_{os}.\) We need to sign

$$ \Updelta =\left( \frac{\partial C}{\partial t_{q}\partial w_{ss}}-\frac{ \partial C}{\partial t_{q}\partial w_{os}}\right) dw_{ss} $$

where dw ss  > 0. By the FOC’s we can write

$$ \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial C}{\partial t_{q}\partial w_{ss}} &=-\frac{w_{os}f^{\prime \prime }\left( t_{os}\right) }{\alpha \left( f^{\prime }\left( t_{os}\right) \right) ^{2}}\frac{\partial t_{os}}{\partial w_{ss}} \\ \frac{\partial C}{\partial t_{q}\partial w_{os}} &=-\frac{w_{ss}f^{\prime \prime }\left( t_{ss}\right) }{\left( f^{\prime }\left( t_{ss}\right) \right) ^{2}}\frac{\partial t_{ss}}{\partial w_{os}} \end{aligned} $$

By Shepard’s Lemma, Young’s Theorem and concavity of the cost function in wage rates \(\partial t_{os}/\partial w_{ss}=\partial t_{ss}/\partial w_{os}>0, \) and we can factor out μ. To sign \(\Updelta,\) we need to compare (\(-f^{\prime \prime }\left( t_{os}\right) /f^{\prime }\left( t_{os}\right) )\) to (\(-f^{\prime \prime }\left( t_{ss}\right) /f^{\prime }\left( t_{ss}\right) )\) where t os  < t ss as our starting point is the cost-minimizing time inputs to produce a certain level of quality time for a girl. If \(-f^{\prime \prime }\left( t_{os}\right) /f^{\prime }\left( t_{os}\right) >-f^{\prime \prime }\left( t_{ss}\right) /f^{\prime }\left( t_{ss}\right) \) marginal cost is higher to produce the same quality time for a boy as for a girl. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 7

Consider a family with a boy. Let B be the optimal child quality and \(x_{B}^{P}\) the optimal parental consumption. Denote the marginal cost of B by \(p_{B}.\) Next, add a fixed amount of full income denoted by I B , so that \(\max_{x^{p},Q^{b}}U\left( x^{p},Q^{b}\right) \) subject to the budget constraint (bc) \(x^{p}+p_{B}Q^{b}=w_{h}+w_{w}+I_{B}\) yields \(\left( x_{B}^{p},B\right).\) Note that \(I_{B}=p_{B}B-\psi ^{b}\left( B\right).\) The same child quality for a girl, Q g = B, has a lower cost. Construct a new bc with parental consumption \(x_{B}^{p}+I_{G}=w_{h}+w_{w}-\psi ^{g}\left( B\right) \) and B on the bc. Note that \(I_{G}=\psi ^{b}\left( B\right) -\psi ^{g}\left( B\right) \) and hence the bc through the point where Q g = B on the actual bc of parents with a girl is given by \(x^{p}+p_{B}Q^{g}=w_{h}+w_{w}+I_{G}.\) Since preferences for (x pQ c) are independent of child sex, and given that goods are normal, the optimal choice for parents of a girl on this bc is \(\left( x_{G}^{p},G\right) \gg \left( x_{B}^{p},B\right).\) Footnote 21 While the optimal bundle for parents with a girl will not in general be \(\left( x_{G}^{p},G\right),\) this inequality together with strictly convex preferences rules out the possibility that the optimal Q g ≤ B. \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gugl, E., Welling, L. Time with sons and daughters. Rev Econ Household 10, 277–298 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-011-9129-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-011-9129-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation