Abstract
While Austrian economists and their models were only indirectly involved in the Cambridge capital theory controversies that came to a dramatic head in 1966, certain ideas argued for by the Cambridge, UK side were prefigured in some work by Austrian economists, especially F.A. Hayek in his 1941, The Pure Theory of Capital, which he wote largely as a result of earlier debates with both Sraffa and Keynes. This paper recounts the roots of the capital theory debates coming out of the nineteenth century, the arguments among Keynes, Sraffa, and Hayek, Hayek’s analysis that undermined traditional Austrian views of capital, the Cambridge controversies themselves, and then how various groups followed up in the aftermath, including neoclassicals, neo-Ricardians and Post Keynesians, and various groups of Austrians, who were themselves slow to recognize the full implications of Hayek’s work and its relation to the Cambridge capital theory controversies. A final point is that among both those following Sraffa and Joan Robinson more as well as those following Hayek more, some have seen the issues leading to broader complexity approaches to capital theory and economic dynamics.
Similar content being viewed by others
Explore related subjects
Discover the latest articles and news from researchers in related subjects, suggested using machine learning.Notes
Petri (2016) provides a good discussion of the development of these ideas from Senior to Böhm-Bawerk through Jevons and Menger. Menger’s views on capital went through various stages with him at times emphasizing aggregate capital.
While Sraffa was thinking through these ideas from the 1920s on, he would not publish his main argument until his famous 1960Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities: A Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory. The record of the development of these ideas is kept in his papers, with Kurz (2013, pp. 59–60)) providing the citations from Sraffa’s papers for these key insights.
Later Cowen (1983) would argue that Lachmann’s point held only in a monetary economy where there would be a common rate of return, whereas Sraffa’s point would hold in a strictly barter general equilibrium.
It must be noted that Irving Fisher (1930) was also aware that irregular time patterns of net returns could complicate his analysis of the “rate of return” as such irregularities, notably negative net returns in future periods, could lead to “multiple roots” in his analysis and thus ambiguity.
Robinson would label this “the Ruth Cohen curiosum” after an actual student of hers, although it appears that the student did not have much to do with developing the idea, if any at all.
That these phenomena generally involve comparing steady-state equilibria would later lead Robinson to dismiss the whole exercise as only mattering in “logical time” rather than the more important “historical time,” thus rendering reswitching to be “unimportant” (Robinson 1975).
It must be noted that many neo-Ricardian Sraffians accept that they follow a classical approach (Kurz 2013), while still maintaining links to the British-based post-Keynesian group, who did not follow the Americans in this dispute.
This paper received an award for being the best paper published in 1976 in Economic Inquiry. The editor (Robert Clower) was not pleased when it was discovered that the paper contained an error (Rosser 1978).
While it was meant to apply to the making of obvious and unrealistic assumptions, Joan Robinson’s wisecrack made in numerous talks although never appearing in print about “a magician who put a rabbit into a hat in full view of the audience, and then expected great applause when he pulled it out again.”
While at the time Rosser was unaware of it, Garegnani (1970) had previously constructed a different example that also exhibited the same phenomenon.
While Lachmann and Shackle saw the subjectivity of heterogeneous capital in plans as crucial and also as drawing on both Hayekian and Keynesian traditions, some later Austrian followers of this strong subjectivism would reject Keynes as retaining an emphasis on aggregate capital (Horwitz 2011).
Samuelson (1966) noted that Solow showed both sides of this contradiction, accepting the critique of aggregate capital in theory, the “red wine” Solow, while using it in his empirical work, the “white wine” Solow. Samuelson said that he preferred the “red wine” Solow of theory, and that when Solow did his “white wine” empirical work he was on a “busman’s holiday,” even as most current neoclassical macroeconomists who rely on Solow’s empirical aggregate production functions are not even aware of his own acceptance of the theoretical critiques of this work.
References
Albin, P. S. (1975). Reswitching: An empirical observation, a theoretical note, and an environmental conjecture. Kyklos, 28, 149–153.
Asheim, G. B. (2008). Paradoxical consumption behavior when economic activity has environmental effects. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 65, 529–546.
Bliss, C. J. (1975). Capital theory and the distribution of income. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Bowles, S., Kirman, A., & Sethi, R. (2017). Retrospectives: Friedrich Hayek and the market algorithm. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 31, 215–230.
Burmeister, E., & van Long, N. (1977). On some unresolved questions in capital theory: An application of Samuelson’s correspondence principle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91, 289–314.
Caldwell, B. (2004). Hayek’s challenge: An intellectual biography of F.A. Hayek. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Carvalho, F. (1983-84). Time in Shacklean and Sraffian economics. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 6, 265–280.
Champernowne, D. G. (1953-54). The production function and the theory of capital: A comment. Review of Economic Studies, 21, 289–318.
Clark, J. B. (1891). Distribution as determined by a law of rent. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 5, 289–318.
Cohen, A. J., & Harcourt, G. C. (2003). Whatever happened to the Cambridge capital theory controversies? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, 199–214.
Cowen, T. (1983). The rate of return. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 5, 608–617.
Davidson, P. A. (1978). Money and the real world. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Davison, P. A. (1982-83). Rational expectations: A fallacious foundation for crucial decision-making processes. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 5, 289–318.
Dvoskin, A., & Petri, F. (2017). Again on the relevance of reverse capital deepening and reswitching. Metroeconomica, 68, 625–659.
Eichner, A. S. (1978). A guide to post-Keynesian economics. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe.
Fisher, I. (1930). The theory of interest. New York: Macmillan.
Garegnani, P. (1966). Switching of techniques. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80, 554–567.
Garegnani, P. (1970). Heterogeneous capital, the production function and the theory of distribution. Review of Economic Studies, 37, 407–436.
Garegnani, P. (1978). Notes on consumption, investment, and effective demand I. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 3, 63–82.
Garrison, R. W. (2001). Time and money: The macroeconomics of capital structures. London: Routledge.
Garrison, R. W. (2006). Reflections on reswitching and roundaboutness. In R. Koppl (Ed.), Money and markets: Essays in honor of Leland B. Yeager (pp. 186–206). London: Routledge.
Gehrke, C., & Kurz, H. D. (2006). Sraffa and von Bortkiewicz: Reconstructing the classical theory of value and distribution. History of Political Economy, 38, 98–149.
Goodwin, R. M. (1951). The nonlinear accelerator and the persistence of business cycles. Econometrica, 19(1), 17.
Hahn, F. H. (1984). Equilibrium and macroeconomics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Han, Z., & Schefold, B. (2006). An empirical investigation of paradoxes: Reswitching and reverse capital deepening in capital theory. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 30, 737–765.
Harcourt, G. C. (1969). Some Cambridge controversies in the theory of capital. Journal of Economic Literature, 7, 369–400.
Harcourt, G. C. (1972). Some Cambridge controversies in the theory of capital. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Harper, D. A., & Endres, A. M. (2010). Capital as a layer cake: A systems approach to capital and its multi-level structure. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 74, 30–41.
Harper, D. A., & Endres, A. M. (2012). The anatomy of emergence with a focus upon capital formation. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 82, 352–367.
Hayek, F. A. (1931a). Reflections on the pure theory of money of Mr. J.M. Keynes, part I. Economica, 11, 270–295.
Hayek, F.A. (1931b). Prices and production. London: Routledge and Sons.
Hayek, F. A. (1932). Money and capital: A reply. Economic Journal, 42, 237–249.
Hayek, F. A. (1937). Economics and knowledge. Economica, 4, 33–54.
Hayek, F. A. (1941). The pure theory of capital. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Hayek, F. A. (1948). Individualism and economic order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Hayek, F.A. (1952).The sensory order: An inquiry into the foundations of theoretical psychology. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
Hayek, F.A. (1967). The theory of complex phenomena, in Studies in philosophy, politics, and economics. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 22–47.
Hicks, J.R. (1977). Economic perspectives: Further essays on money and growth. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Holt, R. P. F., & Pressman, S. (2001). A new guide to post Keynesian economics. London: Routledge.
Horwitz, S. G. (2008). Analogous models of complexity: The Austrian theory of capital and Hayek’s theory of cognition as adaptive classifying systems. Advances in Austrian Economics, 11, 143–166.
Horwitz, S. G. (2011). Contrasting concepts of capital: Another look at the Hayek-Keynes debate. Journal of Private Enterprise, 27, 9–27.
Jevons, W. S. (1866). Brief account of a general mathematical theory of political economy. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 29, 287–297.
Kaldor, N. (1940). A model of the trade cycle. Economic Journal, 50, 78–92.
Keynes, J. M. (1930). A treatise on money. London: Macmillan.
Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan.
Kirzner, I. M. (1966). An essay on capital. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.
Knight, F. M. (1936). The quantity of capital and the rate of interest. Journal of Political Economy, 44, 433–463.
Koppl, R. (2009). Complexity in Austrian economics. In J. B. Rosser Jr. (Ed.), Handbook of complexity research (pp. 393–408). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Koppl, R. (2014). From crisis to confidence: Macroeconomics after the crash. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.
Koppl, R., & Rosser, J. B. Jr. (2002). All that I have to say has already crossed your mind. Metroeconomica, 53, 339–360.
Kurz, H. D. (2013). Sraffa, Keynes, and post-Keynesianism. In G. C. Harcourt & P. Kreisler (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of post-Keynesian economics, volume 1: Theory and origins (pp. 74–100). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Kurz, H. D., & Salvadori, N. (1995). Theory of production. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lachmann, L. M. (1956). Capital and its structure. Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews, and McMeel.
Lachmann, L. M. (1986). The market as an economic process. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Lavoie, D. (1989). Economic chaos or spontaneous order? Implications for political economy of the new view of science. Cato Journal, 8, 613–635.
Levhari, D. (1965). A nonsubstitution theorem and the switching of techniques. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 79, 98–105.
Lewin, P. (1999). Capital in disequilibrium: The role of capital in a changing world. London: Routledge.
Lewin, P. (2014). Hayek and Lachmann. In R. W. Garrison & N. Barry (Eds.), (pp. 165–194). Cheltenham: Elgar companion to Hayekian economics.
Lewin, P., & Cachanasky, N. (2018). Value and capital: Austrian capital theory, retrospect and prospect. Review of Austrian Economics, 31, 1–28.
Lewis, P. (2012). Emergent properties in the work of Friedrich Hayek. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 82, 368–378.
Lewis, P., & Runde, J. (2007). Subjectivism, social structure and the possibility of socio-economic order: The case of Ludwig Lachmann. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 62, 167–186.
Macaulay, F. B. (1938). The movement of interest rates, bond yields and stock prices in the United States since 1856. New York: NBER.
Menger, C. (1888). Zur theorie des kapitals. Jahrbuch für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 1–49.
Morishima, M. (1966). Refutation of the nonsubstitution theorem. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80, 520–525.
Pasinetti, L. (1966). Paradoxes in capital theory: A symposium: Changes in the rate of profit and switches of techniques. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80, 503–517.
Pasinetti, L. (1969). Switches of technique and the ‘rate of return’ in capital theory. Economic Journal, 79, 503–531.
Pasinetti, L. (1981). Structural change and economic growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Pasinetti, L. (1993). Structural economic dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Petri, F. (2016). Capital theory, in Faccarello, G. and Kurz, H.D (eds), History of economic analysis, volume III: developments in major fields of economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 40–69.
Prince, R., & Rosser, J. B. Jr. (1985). Some implications of delayed environmental costs for benefit-cost analysis: A study of reswitching in the western coal lands. Growth and Change, 16, 18–25.
Robinson, J.V. (1953-54). The production function and the theory of capital, Review of Economic Studies, 21, 81=106.
Robinson, J. V. (1956). The accumulation of capital. London: Macmillan.
Robinson, J. V. (1975). The unimportance of reswitching. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 89, 32–39.
Rosser, J. B. Jr. (1978). Continuity and capital-reversal: Comment. Economic Inquiry, 16, 143–146.
Rosser, J. B. Jr. (1983). Reswitching as a cusp catastrophe. Journal of Economic Theory, 31, 182–193.
Rosser, J.B., Jr. (1991). From catastrophe to chaos: A general theory of economic discontinuities. Boston: Kluwer.
Rosser, J. B. Jr. (2006). Complex dynamics and post Keynesian economics. In M. Setterfield (Ed.), Complexity, endogenous money and macroeconomics: Essays in honour of Basil J. Moore (pp. 74–98). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Rosser, J. B. Jr. (2012). Emergence and complexity in Austrian economics. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 81, 122–128.
Rosser, J. B. Jr. (2015). Complexity and Austrian economics. In P. J. Boettke & C. J. Coyne (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of Austrian economics (pp. 594–611). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Samuelson, P. A. (1962). Parable and realism in capital theory: The surrogate production function. Review of Economic Studies, 29, 193–206.
Samuelson, P. A. (1966). A summing up. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80, 568–583.
Senior, N.W. (1836). An outline of the science of political economy. London: W. Clowes & Sons.
Shackle, G. L. S. (1967). The years of high theory: Invention and tradition in economic thought, 1926–1939. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Shackle, G. L. S. (1972). Epistemics and economics: A critique of economic doctrines. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Solow, R. M. (1955-56). The production function and the theory of capital. Review of Economic Studies, 23, 101–106.
Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65–94.
Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 39, 312–320.
Solow, R. M. (1962). Capital theory and the rate of return. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Sraffa, P. (1932a). Dr. Hayek on money and capital. Economic Journal, 42, 42–53.
Sraffa, P. (1932b). A rejoinder. Economic Journal, 42, 249–251.
Sraffa, P. (1936). Letter to Joan Robinson. October 1936. Archives: King’s College, Cambridge.
Sraffa, P. (1960). Production of commodities by commodities: Prelude to a critique of economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Steedman, I. (1977). Marx after Sraffa. London: Verso.
Steedman, I. (1994). The pure theory of capital of F.A. Hayek. In M. Colonna, H. Hagemann, & O. Hamouda (Eds.), Capitalism, socialism and knowledge. The economics of F.A. Hayek, vol. II (pp. 3–25). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.
Steele, G. R. (2014). Hayek’s pure theory of capital. In R. W. Garrison & N. Barry (Eds.), Elgar companion to Hayekian economics (pp. 71–93). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Vaughn, K. I. (1999). Hayek’s thought and market order as an instance of the theory of complex adaptive systems. Journal des économistes et des études humaines, 9, 241–246.
Veblen, T. (1908). Professor Clark’s economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 22, 147–195.
von Böhm-Bawerk, E. (1889). Positive theorie des kapitales. Innsbruck: Wagner.
von Bortkiewicz, L. (1906–07). Wertrechnung und preisrechnung im Marxschen system, Archhiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik, 23, 1–50; 25, 10–51, 455–488.
von Mises, L. (1912). Theorie des geldes und der umlaufsmittel. Munich: Verlag von. Duncker & Humblot.
Vriend, N. J. (2002). Was Hayek an ace? Southern Economic Journal, 68, 811–840.
Wicksell, G.K. (1898). Geldzins und güterpreise: eine studie über die den tauschwert des geldes bestimenden uraschen. Heidelberg: Heidelberg Universitatbibliothek.
Wicksell, G. K. (1911). Föreläsninger: nationalekonomi: I. Lund: Berlingska.
Yeager, L. B. (1976). Toward understanding some paradoxes in capital theory. Economic Inquiry, 14, 313–346.
Yeager, L. B., & Burmeister, E. (1978). Continuity and capital-reversal: Reply. Economic Inquiry, 16, 147–149.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Rosser, J.B. Austrian themes and the Cambridge capital theory controversies. Rev Austrian Econ 33, 415–431 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-018-0431-6
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-018-0431-6