Skip to main content
Log in

The time structure of production in the US, 2002–2009

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The US time structure of production during the 2002 through 2009 business cycle is characterized empirically using industry-level input-output data. An industry’s total industry output requirement (TIOR) is proposed as a metric for “roundaboutness”. I find that the time structure of production lengthened following the Federal Reserve’s 2002 expansionary deviation from the Taylor rule and then contracted during the Great Recession. Value added growth in the most-roundabout of US industries accelerated relative to that of the least-roundabout industries. Heading into the Great Recession, value-added growth in the most-roundabout industries contracted early and turned negative in 2007 while value-added growth in the least-roundabout industries remained positive until 2009. The stylized facts of the time structure of production are consistent with Austrian Business Cycle Theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Young (2011) argues more thoroughly for the development of discriminating, quantitative hypotheses from ABCT. Young (2005) offers and tests such a hypothesis using quarterly job creation and destruction data for the US economy from 1972 through 1993.

  2. As Callahan and Horwitz (2010, p. 220) state: “If the central bank pursues a discretionary, rather than a rule-oriented, monetary policy, then the particular ideas of the chief central banker […] must be taken into account by participants in the markets affected by central bank policy.”

  3. As of this writing, the latest US Department of Labor report is for April of 2011 with the unemployment rate at 9.0 percent.

  4. http://www.bea.gov/industry/iotables/help_section.cfm#glossary

  5. Similar statements can be derived using an additive value-added assumption in place of (3), i.e., X i+1  = X i  + R.

  6. See Barnett and Block (2006) for a critique and, ultimately, an almost complete rejection of the use of Hayekian triangles.

  7. This will be true even if a larger or smaller number of firms allocate their time during the same “calendar time” interval. There are certainly analogs between the underlying intuition my using the TIOR and Skousen’s (1993, 2001, 2007) arguments in favor of aggregate gross output (GO) as a superior macroeconomic aggregate to GDP.

  8. http://www.bea.gov/industry/io_annual.htm

  9. For industries 561 (“Administrative and Support Services”), 42 (“Wholesale Trade”), 531 (“Real Estate”), 44 (“Retail Trade”), and 532 (“Rental and Leasing Services and Lessors of Intangible Assets”) from the LR subsample I substituted the related industries, respectively, 5613 (“Employment Services”), 425 (“Wholesale Trade Agents and Brokers”), 5312 (“Offices of Real Estate Agents and Brokers”), 443111, 4441, & 445110 (“Household Appliance Stores”, “Home Centers”, & “Supermarkets and Other Grocery Stores”), and 5321 (“Automotive Equipment Rental and Leasing”).

  10. Source: US Energy Information Administration (http://www.eia.doe.gov/steo/fsheets/index.cfm).

References

  • Barnett, W., II, & Block, B. (2006). On Hayekian triangles. Procesos De Mercado: Revista Europea De Economia Politica, 3(2), 39–141.

    Google Scholar 

  • Callahan, G., & Horwitz, S. (2010). The role of ideal types in Austrian business cycle theory. In R. Koppl, S. Horwitz, & P. Desrochers (Eds.), Advances in Austrian business cycle theory. Bingley: Emerald.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlstrom, C. T., & Fuerst, T. S. (2003). The Taylor rule: a guidepost for monetary policy? Economic Commentary, July (http://www.clevelandfed.org/Research/commentary/2003/0703.pdf).

  • Cochran, J. P. (2001). Capital-based macroeconomics: recent developments and extensions of Austrian business cycle theory. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 4(3), 17–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (2001). Time and money: The macroeconomics of capital structure. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (2005). The Austrian school: Capital-based macroeconomics. In B. Snowdon & H. R. Vane (Eds.), Modern macroeconomics: Its origin, development and current state. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1933). Monetary theory and the trade cycle. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1935). Prices and production. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keeler, J. P. (2001). Empirical evidence of the Austrian business cycle theory. Review of Austrian Economics, 14(4), 331–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koppl, R. (2002). Big players and the economic theory of expectations. London and New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Koppl, R., & Yeager, L. B. (1996). Big players and herding in asset markets: the case of the Russian ruble. Explorations in Economic History, 33, 367–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1990). Business cycles: real facts and a monetary myth. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 14, 3–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menger, C. (2007) [1871]. Principles of economics. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Mises, L. (1934). The theory of money and credit. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, R. F. (2002). A Hayekian analysis of the term structure of production. The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 5(2), 17–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prescott, E. C. (1986). Theory ahead of business cycle measurement. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 10, 9–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skousen, M. (1993). Economics on trial. Homewood: Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skousen, M. (2001). Beyond GDP: A breakthrough in national income accounting. Ideas on Liberty, April, 53–54.

  • Skousen, M. (2007). The structure of production with a new introduction. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. B. (1993). Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 195–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. B. (2009). Getting off track: How government actions and interventions caused, prolonged, and worsened the financial crisis. Stanford: Hoover Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. T. (2005). Reallocating labor to initiate changes in capital structures: Hayek revisited. Economics Letters, 89(3), 275–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. T. (2011). Illustrating the importance of Austrian business cycle theory: A reply to Murphy, Barnett, and Block; A call for quantitative study. Review of Austrian Economics, 24(1), 19–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrew T. Young.

Additional information

I thank an anonymous referee for helpful comments.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Young, A.T. The time structure of production in the US, 2002–2009. Rev Austrian Econ 25, 77–92 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-011-0158-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-011-0158-0

Keywords

JEL Codes

Navigation