Skip to main content
Log in

The fragility of a discipline when a model has monopoly status

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider the consequences of a scientific literature with only one model of an important phenomenon. The falsification of the model would mean falsification of the science. Scientists who would prefer not to have their discipline falsified will be tempted to find ad hoc explanations to excuse the failure. To test this hypothesis we propose a study of the economic forecasts of the comparative Soviet and American growth rates in the years before a public choice model of central planning was a viable alternative to the public interest model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Adams, B. (2005). Tiny Revolutions In Russia: Twentieth-Century Soviet And Russian History In Anecdotes. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berliner, J. S. (1957). Factory and Manager in the USSR. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1959). “Positive Economics, Welfare Economics, and Political Economy.” Journal of Law and Economics 2, 124–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F. and Thaler, R. H. (1995). “Anomalies: Ultimatums, Dictators and Manners.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, 209–219

    Google Scholar 

  • Conquest, R. (2000). Reflections on a Ravaged Century. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deming W. E. (1965). “Principles of Professional Statistical Practice.” The Annals of Mathematical Statistics 36, 1883–1900.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denton, F. (1985). “Data Mining as an Industry.” Review of Economics and Statistics 57, 124–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth, F. Y. (1881). Mathematical Psychics. London: C. Kegan Paul & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrant, A. (2004). “Frank Knight, worst-case theorizing, and economic planning: socialism as monopoly politics.” History of Political Economy 36, 497–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. (1960). Soviet Statistics of Physical Output of Industrial Commodities: Their Complication and Quality. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

  • Hoffman, E., K. A. McCabe and V. L. Smith (1996). “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games.” American Economic Review 86, 653–660.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., K. A., McCabe and V. L. Smith (1999). “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games: Reply,” American Economic Review 89, 340–341.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. H. [1944 (1932)]. “Social Science and Political Trend.” In F. H. Knight. Freedom and Reform, pp. 19–44. New York and London: Harper & Brothers.

  • Leamer, E. E. (1983). “Let's Take the Con Out of Econometrics.” American Economic Review 73, 31–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levy, D. M. (1990). “The Bias in Centrally Planned Prices.” Public Choice 67, 213–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, D. M. and S. J. Peart (2006). “Inducing Transparency: Towards a Code of Ethics in Econometrics.” Eastern Economic Journal. Forthcoming.

  • Mill, J. S. [1969 (1861)]. Utilitarianism. In: Robson, J. M. (Ed) Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, 10: 205–259. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

  • Nutter, G. W. (1962). Growth of Industrial Production in the Soviet Union. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nutter, G. W. (1969). The Strange World of Ivan Ivanov. New York: World Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peart, S. J and D. M Levy. (2005). ‘The Vanity of the Philosopher': From Equality to Hierarchy in Post-Classical Economics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi, M. (1962). “The Republic of Science: Its Political and Economic Theory.” Minerva 1, 54–74

  • Rubinstein, A. (2000). Economics and Language. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, H. (1973). “Meaning and Reference.” The Philosophy of Language. In: Martinich. : A. P. (Ed.) New York: Oxford University Press, 1996.

  • Sally, D. (2001). “On Sympathy and Games.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 44, 1–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1961). Economics. 5th edition. New York. McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1967). Economics. 7th edition. New York. McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1970). Economics. 8th edition. New York. McGraw-Hill.

  • Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny (1992). “Pervasive Shortages Under Socialism.” Rand Journal of Economics 23, 237–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. [2004 (1759)]. Theory of Moral Sentiments. http://www.econlib.org.

  • Smith, A. [2004 (1776)]. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. http://www.econlib.org

  • Tetlock, P. E. (2005). Expert Political Judgement: How Good Is It? How Can We Know? Princeton: Princeton University Press.”

  • Vardeman, S. B. and M. D. Morris (2003). “Statistics and Ethics: Some Advice for Young Statisticians.” American Statistician 57, 21–26.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David M. Levy.

Additional information

JEL Code A11, B23

Earlier versions of the paper were presented at the University of Manitoba Economics Department Retreat in October 2005 and at the Center for Study of Public Choice Wednesday Seminar in November 2005. We thank the participants for their suggestions. All the remaining errors are our responsibility.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Levy, D.M., Peart, S.J. The fragility of a discipline when a model has monopoly status. Rev Austrian Econ 19, 125–136 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-006-7344-5

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-006-7344-5

Keywords

Navigation