Skip to main content
Log in

District magnitude and representation of the majority’s preferences: a comment and reinterpretation

  • COMMENTARY TO
  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

A REPLY FROM to this article was published on 27 November 2012

The Original Article was published on 14 January 2011

Abstract

Drawing on new data that combine recorded votes from the Swiss National Assembly with canton-level referendum results on identical legislative proposals, Portmann et al. (Public Choice 151:585–610, 2012) develop an innovative strategy to identify the effect of district magnitude on the relationship between representatives and their constituents. We replicate PSE’s central result and also estimate a related model that allows for the possibility of non-monotonicity in the relationship between district magnitude and representatives’ deviance from referendum median voters. Our results indicate that representatives elected in low-magnitude multi-member districts deviate from canton-level majorities less than either MPs from single-member districts or those from high-magnitude multi-member districts.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. An exception, focused on the effects of ballot technologies on voters’ abilities to make choices among a crowded field, is Shocket et al. (1992).

  2. PSE label this variable Canton = CH. We relabeled this variable to make it more transparent for non-Swiss readers.

  3. Like PSE, we estimate logistic regressions with robust standard errors, clustering on canton in recognition of the likelihood that the behavior of MPs from the same district are not independent.

  4. Overall, the rate of MPs voting against cantonal majorities is 32 %.

  5. As a robustness check we estimated all models with fixed effects for each referendum issue, and the results are identical to the results in Table 2. We also ran a variant of the alternative specification with the largest-magnitude districts (DM > 20) as the omitted category, to confirm whether districts in the lower-DM categories were statistically discernible from those at the high end. The results of this estimation are available from the authors.

  6. Table 2 reports both pseudo-R2 and the area under the receiver operating characteristic (ROC) curve—the ratio of deviations from popular majorities correctly versus incorrectly predicted. In terms of overall model fit, our alterative specification offers a slightly larger, but still quite modest, improvement over the basic model in PSE. None of the other alternative specifications tested (e.g., including squared or cubed permutations of the Seats variable) provides even as much of a marginal improvement in overall fit as does the specification with our series of district magnitude dummies.

References

  • Auth, P. (2006). De un sistema proporcional excluyente a uno incluyente. Mimeo (pp. 1–21). Santiago: Fundacion Chile.

  • Baddeley, A. (1994). The magical number 7—still magic after all these years. Psychological Review, 101(2), 353–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carey, J. M., & Hix, S. (2011). The electoral sweet spot: low-magnitude proportional electoral systems. American Journal of Political Science, 55(2), 383–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, E. C. C. (2008). Electoral incentives and budgetary spending: rethinking the role of political institutions. The Journal of Politics, 70(4), 1086–1097.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, E. C. C. & Golden, M. (2007). Electoral systems, district magnitude and corruption. British Journal of Political Science, 37, 115–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, E. C. C., Kayser, M. A., Linzer, D. A., & Rogowski, R. (2011). Electoral systems and the balance of Consumer-producer power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W. (1987). Electoral equilibria under alternative voting institutions. American Journal of Political Science, 31, 82–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W. (1990). Centripetal and centrifugal incentives in electoral systems. American Journal of Political Science, 34, 903–935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W. (1997). Making votes count: strategic coordination in the world’s electoral systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A., Kats, A., & Slutsky, S. (1985). Multi-agent equilibria with market share and ranking objectives. Social Choice and Welfare, 2, 95–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gagliarducci, S., Nannicini, T., & Naticchioni, P. (2011). Electoral rules and politicians’ behavior: a micro test. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 3(3), 144–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golden, M. A., & Picci, L. (2008). Pork-barrel politics in postwar Italy, 1953–1994. American Journal of Political Science, 52(2), 268–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallerberg, M., & Marier, P. (2004). Executive authority, the personal vote, and budget discipline in Latin American and Caribbean countries. American Journal of Political Science, 48(3), 571–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J. D., & Powell, G. B. Jr. (1994). Congruence between citizens and policymakers in two visions of liberal democracy. World Politics, 46(3), 291–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2006). Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: why some democracies redistribute more than others. American Political Science Review, 100(2), 165–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2001). The provision of public goods under alternative electoral incentives. American Economic Review, 91(1), 225–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G. A. (1956). The magical number seven, plus or minus two: some limits on our capacity for processing information. Psychological Review, 63, 81–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moser, R. G., & Scheiner, E. (2012). Electoral systems and political context: how electoral systems differ in new and established democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nohlen, D. (2006). La reforma del sistema binominal desde una perspectiva comparada. Revista de Ciência Política, 26, 191–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, J. H., & Jensen, N. (2007). Electoral competition and agricultural support in OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science, 51(2), 314–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Portmann, M., Stadelmann, D., & Eichenberger, R. (2012). District magnitude and representation of the majority’s preferences: evidence from popular and parliamentary votes. Public Choice, 151, 585–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, G. B., & Vanberg, G. (2000). Election laws, disproportionality and median correspondence: implications for two visions of democracy. British Journal of Political Science, 30(3), 383–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Primo, D. M., & Snyder, J. M. Jr. (2010). Party strength, the personal vote, and government spending. American Journal of Political Science, 54(2), 354–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shocket, P. A., Heighberger, N. R., & Brown, C. (1992). The effect of voting technology on voting behavior in a simulated multi-candidate city council election: a political experiment of ballot transparency. The Western Political Quarterly, 45(2), 521–537.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera, R., & Shugart, M. (1989). Seats and votes: the effects and determinants of electoral systems. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomz, M., Wittenberg, J., & King, G. (2003). Clarify: Software for interpreting and presenting statistical results. Public domain software available at: http://GKing.Harvard.Edu.

  • Wright, J. (2010). Aid effectiveness and the politics of personalism. Comparative Political Studies, 43(6), 735–762.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors want to express their sincere gratitude to Portmann, Stadelmann, and Eichenberger for their immediate willingness to share data, and for their engagement in a productive exchange of ideas about their research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John M. Carey.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Carey, J.M., Hix, S. District magnitude and representation of the majority’s preferences: a comment and reinterpretation. Public Choice 154, 139–148 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-0023-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-0023-0

Keywords

Navigation