Skip to main content
Log in

Childlessness, celibacy and net fertility in pre-industrial England: the middle-class evolutionary advantage

  • Published:
Journal of Economic Growth Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper reconsiders the fertility of historical social groups by accounting for singleness and childlessness. We find that the middle class had the highest reproductive success during England’s early industrial development. In light of the greater propensity of the middle class to invest in human capital, the rise in the prevalence of these traits in the population could have been instrumental to England’s economic success. Unlike earlier results about the survival of the richest, the paper shows that the reproductive success of the rich (and also the poor) were lower than that of the middle class, once accounting for singleness and childlessness. Hence, the prosperity of England over this period can be attributed to the increase in the prevalence of middle-class traits rather than those of the upper (or lower) class.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Data from Table F.1

Similar content being viewed by others

Explore related subjects

Discover the latest articles and news from researchers in related subjects, suggested using machine learning.

Notes

  1. The Wrigley et al. (1997) net reproduction rates have to be multiplied by two to capture both males and females, but they average 2.37 from 1536 to 1780 far lower than the values coming from the Clark and Cummins (2015) will database.

  2. As is clear in our demographic measures below, farmers are often an outlier group. We suspect that farmers organised themselves differently with regards to family planning than other segments of society for two reasons. They were much more closely affected by inheritance rules and the division of farm land between offspring, and as food suppliers they responded in the opposite manner to variations in food prices than all other groups who were food demanders.

  3. We also ran other models with a greater number of time periods, one for each decade, but this did not influence our results.

  4. The Cox proportional hazard model assumes, as its name indicates, that the hazard rate is shifted proportionately by the control variables. It implies that the survival functions for different social classes change proportionately and do not, for instance, cross each other. One test of the proportionality assumption (by Grambsch and Therneau (1994)) is obtained by computing, for each control variable, the scaled Schoenfeld residual, and by correlating it with a transformation of time (Hosmer and Lemeshow 1999, pp. 197–205; Schoenfeld 1982); proportionality is rejected if the correlation is statistically significant. In the case of our regression, the correlations are respectively 0.01 (Husbandmen), 0.01 (Craftsmen), 0.00 (Traders), -0.02 (Farmers), -0.00 (Upper class), and none of them is statistically different from zero.

  5. We tested for regional variation in the marriage rates by grouping our parishes into three regions: North, Midlands and South. The upper classes had lower risks of marriage in all regions and statistically signicant differences in the Midlands and South. However, the gradient appears to hold across all regions (not reported).

  6. Note that childbirth outside of wedlock was banned by the Church of England, and that illegitimate births, therefore, were rare ranging from 1.2 to 6.0% of births across our period (Wrigley et al. 1997, p. 224).

  7. Leridon (2008) measures natural sterility in the Henry database for rural eighteenth century France when fertility control was ineffective. Restricting the sample to couples where the husband and the wife were still living together at age 50, 3.7% of women who married at age 20–24 remained childless.

  8. We also test for proportionality here. The correlation between the scaled Schoenfeld residual and transformation of time are respectively 0.01 (Husbandmen), 0.00 (Craftsmen), 0.01 (Traders), 0.00 (Farmers), 0.03 (Upper class), and none of them is statistically different from zero, but for the Upper class. In addition to the proportionality assumption, it is also possible to test the assumption of the Cox model that censoring is independent from survival time. We have reasons to believe that it might be violated in the case of childlessness, as sterility and death have common unobserved determinants. We consider this issue in Appendix I, using the method proposed by Jackson et al. (2014) and find that it is not important for our results.

  9. Again, we tested for regional variation in the childlessness rates by grouping our parishes into three regions: North, Midlands and South. The upper classes had lower risks of first birth in all regions but the differences were only statistically significant in the South. However, the gradient appears to hold across all regions (not reported).

  10. The proportionality of the hazard rates is less clearly supported for the birth estimations than for the two extensive margins. Among the 63 coefficients in Table 4, proportionality is rejected in 26 cases (at the 5% level). However, this non-proportionality is not overly concerning because we are estimating the parity progression ratios over a short period of time (the cumulated hazard over 10 years rather than 30 years for marriage rates), and non-proportionality is less likely to be an issue over short time intervals (Bellera et al. 2010).

  11. Moreover, the proportionality of hazards is never rejected.

  12. We break the margins down further in Appendix D. This gradient also matches what one would find from a simple count of the number of children surviving to women sorted by the woman’s father’s occupation (see Appendix E.

  13. We use the imputation method described in the next section (Sect. 4.6) to aggregate the uncertainty around the estimates for the four margins estimated above.

  14. One might also wonder what would happen if those with unknown occupations were able to be assigned to their correct occupational categories. The unknown category has lower net reproduction than the other groups. Part of this is driven by the sources of occupations, which leads us to underestimate births and overestimate childlessness for that group, and is discussed at length in Sect. 5.3 and Appendix L. If we assume that the vast majority of the unknown were lower classes and reallocate all of the unknown into the lower class category, the net reproduction of the lower classes becomes statistically lower than both the middle and upper classes. However, the middle classes would still have far higher fertility than the upper classes, which is what is important for our story. The hump-shaped gradient would only become more accentuated.

  15. Note that we do not lose any parishes in this robustness check because the parishes with data after 1780 all have starting dates before 1680. Thus, there are 26 parishes in all of the analysis.

  16. Ruggles (1992) and Wrigley (1994) have also discussed potential migration biases to mean ages at marriage and death in reconstitution studies. These are discussed in more detail in Appendix J.

  17. We are not surprised that women have a slightly higher emigration rate than men in this case. We are mostly measuring migration over very small distances, given that a migrant is simply someone who leaves their parish of birth. We would not be surprised, then, if relatively few women migrated long distances and most women migrants simply moved into their husband’s parish nearby. As such, our findings do not challenge the common understanding that men have a higher propensity to emigrate.

  18. See Appendix D and Figure D.1 for more detail.

References

  • Aaronson, D., Lange, F., & Mazumder, B. (2014). Fertility transitions along the extensive and intensive margins. American Economic Review, 104(11), 3701–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Althaus, P. G. (1980). Differential fertility and economic growth. Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft / Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 136(2), 309–326.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, M. (1990). The social implications of demographic change. In F. M. L. Thompson (Ed.), The Cambridge Social History of Britain, 1750–1950 (Vol. 2, pp. 1–70). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, W. A. (1972). The use of information about occupation. In E. A. Wrigley (Ed.), Nineteenth-century society: Essays in the use of quantitative methods for the study of social data (pp. 191–310). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ashraf, Q., & Galor, O. (2011). Dynamics and stagnation in the Malthusian epoch. American Economic Review, 101(5), 2003–2041.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardet, J.-P. (1983). Rouen au XVII \(^e\) et XVIII \(^e\) siècles. Paris: SEDES.

  • Baudin, T., de la Croix, D., & Gobbi, P. E. (2015). Fertility and childlessness in the US. American Economic Review, 105, 1852–1882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baudin, T., de la Croix, D., & Gobbi, P. E. (2020). Endogenous childlessness and stages of development. Journal of the European Economic Association (forthcoming).

  • Bellera, C. A., MacGrogan, G., Debled, M., de Lara, C. T., Brouste, V., & Mathoulin-Pélissier, S. (2010). Variables with time-varying effects and the Cox model: some statistical concepts illustrated with a prognostic factor study in breast cancer. BMC Medical Research Methodology, 10(1), 20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belsey, M. A. (1976). The epidemiology of infertility: a review with particular reference to sub-Saharan Africa. Bulletin of the World Health Organization (WHO), 54(3), 319–341.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bengtsson, T., & Dribe, M. (2006). Deliberate control in a natural fertility population: Southern Sweden, 1766–1864. Demography, 43(4), 727–746.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackstone, W., & Kerr, R. M. N. (1896). The student’s blackstone: Being the commentaries on the Laws of England of Sir William Blackstone. London: Reeves and Turner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boberg-Fazlic, N., Sharp, P., & Weisdorf, J. (2011). Survival of the richest? Social status, fertility and social mobility in England 1541–1824. European Review of Economic History, 15, 365–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. (2007). Genetically capitalist? Science, 318(5849), 394–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheneys. (1967). Cheneys of Banbury, 1767–1967. Cheneys & Sons.

  • Cinnirella, F., Klemp, M., & Weisdorf, J. (2017). Malthus in the bedroom: Birth spacing as birth control in pre-transition England. Demography, 54(2), 413–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G. (2007). A farewell to alms: A brief economic history of the world. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G., & Cummins, N. (2015). Malthus to modernity: Wealth, status, and fertility in England, 1500–1879. Journal of Population Economics, 28(1), 3–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G., & Hamilton, G. (2006). Survival of the richest: The Malthusian mechanism in Pre-Industrial England. The Journal of Economic History, 66(3), 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, P. (1979). Migration in England during the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries. Past & Present, 83, 57–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cressy, D. (1981). Levels of illiteracy in England, 1530–1730. In H. A. Graff (Ed.), Literacy and social development in the west: A reader (pp. 105–124). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crouzet, F. (1985). The first industrialists. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • De Moor, T., & Van Zanden, J. L. (2010). Girl power: The European marriage pattern and labour markets in the North Sea region in the late medieval and early modern period. Economic History Review, 63(1), 1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix, D. (2012). Fertility, education, growth, and sustainability. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix, D., & Brée, S. (2019). Key forces behind the decline of fertility: Lessons from childlessness in rouen before the industrial revolution. Cliometrica, 13(1), 25–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix, D., & Doepke, M. (2003). Inequality and growth: Why differential fertility matters. American Economic Review, 93(4), 1091–1103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix, D., Doepke, M., & Mokyr, J. (2018). Clans, guilds, and markets: Apprenticeship institutions and growth in the Pre-Industrial Economy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133, 1–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dennison, T., & Ogilvie, S. (2014). Does the European marriage pattern explain economic growth? The Journal of Economic History, 74(03), 651–693.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Pleijt, A. M. (2018). Human capital formation in the long run: Evidence from average years of schooling in England, 1300–1900. Cliometrica, 12(1), 99–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Pleijt, A. M., Nuvolari, A., & Weisdorf, J. (2019). Human Capital formation during the first industrial revolution: Evidence from the use of steam engines. Journal of the European Economic Association (early view).

  • Doepke, M., & Zilibotti, F. (2008). Occupational choice and the spirit of capitalism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 747–793.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feeney, G. (1986). Period parity progression measures of fertility in Japan. NUPRI Research Paper Series 35.

  • Fildes, V. A. (1986). Breasts, bottles and babies: A history of infant feeding. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foreman-Peck, J. (2011). The Western European marriage pattern and economic development. Explorations in Economic History, 48(2), 292–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Froide, A. M. (2005). Never married: Singlewomen in early modern England. Cambridge: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O. (2012). Unified growth theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Klemp, M. (2019). Human genealogy reveals selective advantge to moderate fecundity. Nature Ecology & Evolution, 3, 853–857.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Michalopoulos, S. (2012). Evolution and the growth process: Natural selection of entrepreneurial traits. Journal of Economic Theory, 147(2), 759–780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2001). Evolution and growth. European Economic Review, 45(4–6), 718–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2002). Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1133–1191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gobbi, P. E. (2013). A model of voluntary childlessness. Journal of Population Economics, 26(3), 963–982.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gobbi, P. E., & Goñi, M. (2016). Childless aristocrats. Fertility, inheritance, and persistent inequality in Britain (1550–1950). unpublished.

  • Goñi, M. (2015). Kissing cousins. Estimating the causal effect of consanguinity on fertility using evidence from the London Season. unpublished.

  • Grambsch, P. M., & Therneau, T. M. (1994). Proportional hazards tests and diagnostics based on weighted residuals. Biometrika, 81(3), 515–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hajnal, J. (1965). European marriage patterns in perspective. In D. E. Eversley & D. V. Glass (Eds.), Population in history: Essays in historical demography (pp. 101–43). Chicago: Chicago Illinois Aldine Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henry, L. (1953). Fécondité des Mariages - Nouvelle méthode de mesure. Paris: Presses Universitaire de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, L. (1983). Wives and property. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hollingsworth, T. H. (1965). The demography of the British peerage. London: Population Investigation Committee, LSE.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hosmer, D. W., & Lemeshow, S. (1999). Applied survival analysis: Regression modelling of time to event data. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, D., White, I., Seaman, S., Evans, H., Baisleyb, K., & Carpenter, J. (2014). Relaxing the independent censoring assumption in the Cox proportional hazards model using multiple imputation. Statistics in Medicine, 33, 4681–4694.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jeub, U. N. (1993). Parish records: 19th century ecclesiastical registers. Umeå: Demografiska databasen, Univ.

  • Kelly, M., & Gráda, C. Ó. (2012). The preventive check in medieval and Preindustrial England. The Journal of Economic History, 72(04), 1015–1035.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klemp, M., Minns, C., Wallis, P., & Weisdorf, J. (2013). Picking winners? The effect of birth order and migration on parental human capital investments in pre-modern England. European Review of Economic History, 17(2), 210–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landers, J. (1993). Death and the metropolis: Studies in the demographic history of London, 1670–1830 (Vol. 20). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J., Feng, W., & Li, B. (2000). Population, poverty, and subsistence in China, 1700–2000. In T. Bengtsson & O. Saito (Eds.), Population and economy: From hunger to modern economic growth (pp. 73–109). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leridon, H. (2008). A new estimate of permanent sterility by age: Sterility defined as the inability to conceive. Population Studies, 62(1), 15–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leunig, T., Minns, C., & Wallis, P. (2011). Networks in the premodern economy: The market for London apprenticeships, 1600–1749. The Journal of Economic History, 71(2), 413–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Livi-Bacci, M. (1986). Social group forerunners of fertility control in Europe. In A. Coale & S. C. Watkins (Eds.), The decline of fertility in Europe (pp. 182–200). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long, J. (2013). The surprising social mobility of Victorian Britain. European Review of Economic History, 17(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malthus, T. R. (1798). An essay on the principle of population. London: Johnson.

  • Minns, C., & Wallis, P. (2012). Rules and reality: Quantifying the practice of apprenticeship in early modern England. The Economic History Review, 65(2), 556–579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2005). Long-term economic growth and the history of technology. In P. Aghion & S. N. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 1, pp. 1113–1180). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parascandola, J. (2008). Sex, sin, and science: A history of syphilis in America. Westport: Greenwood Publishing Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruggles, S. (1992). Migration, marriage, and mortality: Correcting sources of bias in English family reconstitutions. Population Studies, 46(3), 507–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schoenfeld, D. (1982). Partial residuals for the proportional hazards regression model. Biometrika, 69(1), 239–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, R. (1985). English marriage patterns revisited. Journal of Family History, 10, 2–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, R. S. (1981). Dimensions of illiteracy in England, 1750–1850. In H. A. Graff (Ed.), Literacy and social development in the West: A reader (pp. 201–213). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaw-Taylor, L., & Wrigley, E. A. (2014). Occupational structure and population change. In J. H. R. Floud & P. Johnson (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of modern Britain: Volume 1, Industrialisation, 1700–1870 (pp. 53–88). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Skirbekk, V., et al. (2008). Fertility trends by social status. Demographic Research, 18(5), 145–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Squicciarini, M. P., & Voigtländer, N. (2015). Human capital and industrialization: Evidence from the age of enlightenment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(4), 1825–1883.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, L. (1979). The family sex and marriage: In England 1500–1800. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Szreter, S. (2014). The prevalence of Syphilis in England and Wales on the eve of the great war: Re-visiting the estimates of the Royal Commission on Venereal Diseases 1913–1916. Social History of Medicine, 27(3), 508–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szreter, S. (2017). Treatment rates for the pox in early modern England: A comparative estimate of the prevalence of syphilis in the city of Chester and its rural vicinity in the 1770s. Continuity and Change, 32(2), 183–223.

  • Van de Walle, E., & Van de Walle, F. (1972). Allaitement, stérilité et contraception: les opinions jusqu’au XIXe siècle. Population, 27(4), 685–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Leeuwen, M. H. D., & Maas, I. (2011). HISCLASS: A historical international social class scheme. Leuven: Universitaire Pers Leuven.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogl, T. (2016). Differential fertility, human capital, and development. Review of Economic Studies, 83, 365–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigtländer, N., & Voth, H.-J. (2013). The three horsemen of riches: Plague, war, and urbanization in Early Modern Europe. Review of Economic Studies, 80(2), 774–811.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallis, P., & Webb, C. (2011). The education and training of gentry sons in early modern England. Social History, 36(1), 36–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weir, D. R. (1984). Rather never than late: celibacy and age at marriage in English cohort fertility, 1541–1871. Journal of Family History, 9(04), 340–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley, E. A. (1966). Family reconstitution. In D. E. C. Eversley, P. Laslett, & E. A. Wrigley (Eds.), An introduction to english historical demography: From the sixteenth to the nineteenth century (pp. 96–159). London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley, E. A. (1994). The effect of migration on the estimation of marriage age in family reconstitution studies. Population Studies, 48(1), 81–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley, E. A., Davies, R. S., Oeppen, J., & Schofield, R. (1997). English population history from family reconstitution: 1580–1837. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley, E. A., & Schofield, R. (1981). The population history of England 1541–1871: A reconstruction. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

David de la Croix acknowledges the financial support of the project ARC 15/19-063 of the Belgian French speaking Community. We thank Gregory Clark, Neil Cummins, Oded Galor, James Kung, Carol Shiue, Joachim Voth, Patrick Wallis and participants at the workshops on “The importance of Elites and their demography for Knowledge and Development” (UCLouvain, 2016), “Deep-Rooted Factors in Comparative Development” (Brown, 2017) and the seminar Economics and History (Marseilles, 2017) for comments on an earlier draft. An earlier version of this paper circulated as “Decessit sine prole”—Childlessness, Celibacy, and Survival of the Richest in Pre-Industrial England.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David de la Croix.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 2811 KB)

Supplementary material 2 (zip 13890 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

de la Croix, D., Schneider, E.B. & Weisdorf, J. Childlessness, celibacy and net fertility in pre-industrial England: the middle-class evolutionary advantage. J Econ Growth 24, 223–256 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-019-09170-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-019-09170-6

Keywords

JEL Classification