Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Will progress in science and technology avert or accelerate global collapse? A critical analysis and policy recommendations

  • Published:
Environment, Development and Sustainability Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Industrial society will move towards collapse if its total environmental impact (I), expressed either in terms of energy and materials use or in terms of pollution, increases with time, i.e., dI/dt > 0. The traditional interpretation of the I = PAT equation reflects the optimistic belief that technological innovation, particularly improvements in eco-efficiency, will significantly reduce the technology (T) factor, and thereby result in a corresponding decline in impact (I). Unfortunately, this interpretation of the I = PAT equation ignores the effects of technological change on the other two factors: population (P) and per capita affluence (A). A more heuristic formulation of this equation is I = P(T)·A(T)·T in which the dependence of P and A on T is apparent. From historical evidence, it is clear that technological revolutions (tool-making, agricultural, and industrial) have been the primary driving forces behind successive population explosions, and that modern communication and transportation technologies have been employed to transform a large proportion of the world’s inhabitants into consumers of material- and energy-intensive products and services. In addition, factor analysis from neoclassical growth theory and the rebound effect provide evidence that science and technology have played a key role in contributing to rising living standards. While technological change has thus contributed to significant increases in both P and A, it has at the same time brought about considerable eco-efficiency improvements. Unfortunately, reductions in the T-factor have generally not been sufficiently rapid to compensate for the simultaneous increases in both P and A. As a result, total impact, in terms of energy production, mineral extraction, land-use and CO2 emissions, has in most cases increased with time, indicating that industrial society is nevertheless moving towards collapse. The belief that continued and even accelerated scientific research and technological innovation will automatically result in sustainability and avert collapse is at best mistaken. Innovations in science and technology will be necessary but alone will be insufficient for sustainability. Consequently, what is most needed are specific policies designed to decrease total impact, such as (a) halting population growth via effective population stabilization plans and better access to birth control methods, (b) reducing total matter-energy throughput and pollution by removing perverse subsidies, imposing regulations that limit waste discharges and the depletion of non-renewable resources, and implementing ecological tax reform, and (c) moving towards a steady-state economy in which per-capita affluence is stabilized at lower levels by replacing wasteful conspicuous material consumption with social alternatives known to enhance subjective well-being. While science and technology must play an important role in the implementation of these policies, none will be enacted without a fundamental change in society’s dominant values of growth and exploitation. Thus, value change is the most important prerequisite for avoiding global collapse.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As Pimentel and Pimentel (1996) have shown, there is a strong correlation between global energy use and world population growth, particularly after 1700.

  2. Global production of crude oil is likely to peak within the next decade and decline thereafter (Campbell & Laherrere, 1998; Romm & Curtis, 1996).

  3. A limited resource may be a non-renewable or renewable fuel and mineral, the waste absorption capacity of the environment, or even time.

  4. There are some exceptions: In response to environmental regulations, the release of a few selected pollutants has been reduced significantly or in some cases eliminated completely (see Sect. 6.2 for examples).

  5. The fact that all industrial and economic activities have inherently unavoidable environmental impacts is also supported by the second law of thermodynamics which states that “order” in the techno-sphere can only be created at the expense of generating “disorder” in the biosphere. For a detailed discussion of this topic, see Cleveland and Ruth (1997), Connelly and Koshland (1997), Faber, Niemes, and Stephan (1995), Glasby (1988), Huesemann (2001, 2003), O’Connor (1994), and Ruth (1993, 1995).

  6. It has been argued that GDP can in principle increase “indefinitely” because it only reflects the amount of money circulating through the economy. This is correct but in order for GDP growth to continue without concomitant material consumption, people would have to focus on buying and selling personal services that do not require material and energy resources. This type of GDP growth would not result in a rise in material affluence as has been experienced in the last two centuries (Dresner, 2002, p. 105).

  7. It is interesting to note that even at the molecular level, the active sites of enzymes also become with increasing substrate concentration saturated in a curvilinear fashion (Nelson & Cox, 2005).

  8. In an interesting study of the influence of direct democracy on subjective well-being in different Swiss cantons (states), Frey and Stutzer (2000) found that direct democratic participation via popular referenda had a greater effect on happiness than living in the top rather than in the bottom of the income category.

  9. Some creativity will be needed to express social status in non-consumptive ways. Here we can learn from the military which for many years has successfully employed very simple and inexpensive symbols such as stars and stripes on uniforms to exhibit rank.

  10. Even if the accrued savings are not immediately spent but rather placed in a bank account or otherwise invested, they will eventually be spent in the future. Thus, saving results in delayed consumption.

  11. The average individual income of the global top 20% is around 150 times larger than the bottom 20%. Similarly, the net worth of a few hundred billionaires is equal to the combined “wealth” (or lack thereof) of more than 2 billion of the world’s poorest people (Korten, 1995).

References

  • Abramovitz, M. (1956). Resource and output trends in the United States since 1870. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 46(May), 5–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adriaanse, A. et al. (1997). Resource flows the material basis of industrial economies. Washington, DC: World Resources Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alfredsson, E. C. (2004). Green consumption—no solution for climate change. Energy, 29, 513–524.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Argyle, M. (1987). The psychology of happiness. London: Methuen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ausubel, J. H. (1996). Can technology spare the earth? American Scientist, 84, 166–178, March–April Issue.

  • Ausubel, J. H., & Gruebler, A. (1995). Working less and living longer: Long-term trends in working time and time budgets. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 50, 113–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayres, R. U., & van den Bergh, C. J. M. (2005). A theory of economic growth with material/energy resources and dematerialization: Interaction of three growth mechanisms. Ecological Economics, 55, 96–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayres, R. U., & Warr, B. (2005). Accounting for growth: The role of physical work. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 16, 181–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balzhiser, R. E., Samuels, M. R., & Elisassen, J. D. (1972). Chemical engineering thermodynamics—the study of energy, entropy, and equilibrium. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnard, N. D., Nicholson, A., & Howard, J. L. (1995). The medical costs attributable to meat consumption. Preventative Medicine, 24(6), 646–655.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaudreau, B. C. (2005). Engineering and economic growth. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 16, 211–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beckerman, W. (1996) Through green-colored glasses: Environmentalism reconsidered. Washington, DC: Cato Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bender, W. H. (1994). An end use analysis of global food requirements. Food Policy, 19(4), 381–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentzen, J. (2004). Estimating the rebound effect in US manufacturing energy consumption. Energy Economics, 26, 123–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Betts, K. (2004). Calculating computing’s environmental cost. Environmental Science and Technology, November 15 Issue, 432A–433A.

  • Binswanger, M. (2001). Technological progress and sustainable development: What about the rebound effect? Ecological Economics, 36, 119–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Birdsall, N. (1994). Another look at population and global warming. In Population, environment, and development. Proceedings of the United Nations Expert Group Meeting on Population, Environment, and Development held at the United Nations Headquarters, 20–24 January 1992, New York, United Nations, pp. 39–54.

  • Birol, F., & Keppler, J. H. (2000). Prices, technology development and the rebound effect. Energy Policy, 28, 457–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blair, R. D., Kaserman, D. & Tepel, R. C. (1984). The impact of improved mileage on gasoline consumption. Economic Inquiry, 22, 209–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bongaarts, J. (1992). Population growth and global warming. Population and Development Review, 18(2), 299–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bongaarts, J., O’Neill, B. C. & Gaffin, S. R. (1997). Global warming policy: Population left out of in the cold. Environment, 39(9), 40–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braun, E. (1995). Futile progress: Technology’s empty promise. London, UK: Earthscan Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brookes, L. (2000). Energy efficiency fallacies revisited. Energy Policy, 28, 355–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell C. J., & Laherrere, J. H. (1998). The end of cheap oil. Scientific American, March, 78–83.

  • Carlsson-Kanyama, A. (1998). Climate change and dietary choices—how can emissions of greenhouse gases from food consumption be reduced? Food Policy, 23(3/4), 277–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castaneda, B. (1997). An index of sustainable economic welfare for Chile, institute for ecological economics. Maryland: Solmons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cavanagh, J., & Mander, J. (2002). Alternatives to economic globalization (1st ed.). San Francisco, CA: Berrett-Koehler Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chalkley, A. M., Billett, E., & Harrison, D. (2001). An investigation of the possible extent of the re-spending rebound effect in the sphere of consumer products. The Journal of Sustainable Product Design, 1, 163–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chertow, M. R. (2001). The IPAT equation and its variants, Journal of Industrial Ecology, 4(4), 13–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cleveland, C. J., & Ruth, M. (1997). When, Where and by How much does thermodynamics constrain economic processes? A survey of Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen's contribution to ecological economics. Ecological Economics, 22, 203–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cleveland, C. J., & Ruth, M. (1999). Indicators of dematerialization and the materials intensity of use, Journal of Industrial Ecology, 2, 15–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, L., & Koshland, C. P. (1997). Two aspects of consumption: Using an exergy-based measure of degradation to advance the theory and implementation of industrial ecology, Resource Conservation and Recycling, 19, 199–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, T. (2005). Slower consumption: Reflections on product life spans and the ‘Throwaway Society’. Journal of Industrial Ecology, 9(1–2), 51–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daly, H. E. (1980). The steady-state economy: toward a political economy of biophysical equilibrium and moral growth. In H. E. Daly (Ed.), Economics, ecology, ethics—assays toward a steady-state economy. New York: W.H. Freedman.

  • Daly, H. E., & Cobb, J. (1989). For the common good—redirecting the economy towards community, the environment, and sustainable development. London, UK: Green Print.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deevey, E. S. (1960). The human population. Scientific American, 203, 195–204.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denison, E. F. (1985). Trends in American economic growth: 1929–1982. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, J. (2005). Collapse: How societies choose to fail or succeed. New York, NY: Viking Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diefenbacher, H. (1994). The ISEW in Germany. In C. Cobb & J. Cobb (Eds.), The green national product. Lanham, Maryland: University of Americas Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diener, E., & Oishi, S. (2000). Money and happiness: Income and subjective well-being across nations. In E. Diener, & E. M. Suh (Eds.), Culture and subjective well-being. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, pp. 185–218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dresner, S. (2002). The principles of sustainability. London, UK: Earthscan Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duchin, F. (2005). Sustainable consumption of food. Journal of Industrial Ecology, 9(1–2), 99–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen, F., & Hornig, F. (2004). Der Windmuehlen Wahn—Die Grosse Luftnummer (The Windmill Craze – The Great Air Number). Der Spiegel, 14, 80–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durning, A. T. (1992). How much is enough? The consumer society and the future of the earth. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich, P. R. (1989). The limits to substitution: Meta-resource depletion and a new economic-ecological paradigm. Ecological Economics, 1, 9–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich, P. R., & Ehrlich, A. H. (1991). The population explosion. Touchstone Books.

  • Ehrlich, P. R., & Holdren, J. (1971). Impact of population growth. Science, 171, 1212–1217.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott, D. L., Wendell, L. L., & Gower, G. L. (1992). Wind energy potential in the united states considering environmental and land-use exclusions. In M. E. Ardan, S. M. A. Burley & M. Coleman (Eds.), Proceedings of the biennial congress of the international solar energy society, Solar World Congress in Denver, Colorado, Oxford, UK, Pergamon, Vol. 1(2), pp. 576–581.

  • Faber, M., Niemes, H. & Stephan, G. (1995). Entropy, environment, and resources. Berlin, Germany: Spinger Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabricant, S. (1954). Economic progress and economic change, 34th Annual report of the National Bureau of Economic Research, New York.

  • Frank, R. H. (1999). Luxury fever—Why money fails to satisfy in an era of excess. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2000). Happiness, economy, and institutions. Economics Journal, 110(446), 918–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2002). What can economists learn from happiness research? Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 402–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaffin, S. R. (1998). World population projections for greenhouse gas emission scenarios. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change, 3, 133–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerbens-Leenes, P. W., & Nonhebel, S. (2002). Consumption patterns and their effects on land required for food. Ecological Economics, 42, 185–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glasby, G. P. (1988). Entropy, pollution and environmental degradation. Ambio, 17, 330–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodland, R. (1997). Environmental sustainability in agriculture: Diet matters, Ecological Economics, 23(3), 189–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graedel, T. E., & Allenby, B. R. (1995). Industrial ecology. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, D. L. (1992). Vehicle use and fuel economy: How big is the rebound effect? The Energy Journal, 13(1), 117–143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greening, L. A., Greene, D. L. & Difiglio, C. (2000). Energy efficiency and consumption—the rebound effect—a survey. Energy Policy, 28, 389–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubb, M. J. (1990). Energy efficiency and economic fallacies. Energy Policy, October Issue, pp. 783–785.

  • Gruebler, A. (1994). Industrialization as a historical phenomenon. Industrial Ecology and Global Change, pp. 43–68.

  • Gutes, M. C. (1996). The concept of weak sustainability. Ecological Economics, 17, 147–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haas, R., & Biermayr, P. (2000). The rebound effect for space heating: Empirical evidence from Austria. Energy Policy, 28, 403–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, C. (2003). Growth fetish. NSW Australia: Allen and Unwin, Crows Nest.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hannon, B. (1975). Energy conservation and the consumer. Science, 189(4197), 95–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herring, H. (1999). Does energy efficiency save energy? The debate and its consequences. Applied Energy, 63, 209–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertwich, E. G. (2005). Consumption and the rebound effect: An industrial ecology perspective. Journal of Industrial Ecology, 9(1–2), 85–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hobbs, F., & Stoops, N. (2002). Demographic trends in the 20th century, U.S. Census Bureau, Census 2000 Special Reports, Series CENSR-4, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC, www.census.gov/prod/2002pubs/CENSR-4.pdf.

  • Holdren, J. P. (1991). Population and the energy problem. Population and Environment, 12(3), 231–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howarth, R. (1997). Energy efficiency and economic growth. Contemporary Economic Policy, 15, 1–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huesemann, M. H. (2001). Can pollution problems be effectively solved by environmental science and technology? An analysis of critical limitations. Ecological Economics, 37, 271–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huesemann, M. H. (2003). The limits of technological solutions to sustainable development. Clean Technology and Environmental Policy, 5, 21–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huesemann, M. H. (2006). Can advances in science and technology prevent global warming? A critical review of limitations and challenges. Mitigation and Adaptation for Global Change, 11, 539–577.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inhaber, H., & Saunders, H. (1994). Road to nowhere: Energy conservation often backfires and leads to increased consumption. The Sciences, 34(6), 20–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). (2001). Special report on emission scenarios, www.ipcc.ch.

  • International Center for Technology Assessment (ICTA). (1998). The real price of gasoline, report no. 3: An analysis of the hidden external costs consumers pay to fuel their automobiles, www.icta.org/doc/Real%20Price%20of%20Gasoline.pdf.

  • Jackson, T. (2005). Live better by consuming less? Is there a ‘double dividend’ in sustainable consumption? Journal of Industrial Ecology, 9(1–2), 19–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, T., & Marks, N. (1999). Consumption, sustainable welfare and human needs—with reference to UK expenditure patterns between 1954 and 1994. Ecological Economics, 28, 421–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, T., & Stymne, S. (1996). Sustainable economic welfare in Sweden—a pilot index 1950–1992. Stockholm, Sweden: Stockholm Environment Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jevons, W. S., (1906). The coal question: Can Britain survive? First published in 1865. London, UK: Republished by Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jobling, M. A., Hurles, M. E., & Tyler-Smith, C. (2003). Human evolutionary genetics: Origin, peoples and disease, Garland Science/Francis and Taylor Group.

  • Jochem, E. (2000). Energy and end-use efficiency. In J. Goldemberg (Ed.), World energy assessment: Energy and the challenge of sustainability (pp. 174–217). Chapter 6, United Nations Development Programme, United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, World Energy Council.

  • Kahnemann, D., & Tversky, A. (1984). Choices, values and frames. American Psychologist, 39, 341–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kasser, T., (2002). The high price of materialism. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keeling, C. D., & Whorf, T. P. Atmospheric CO2 concentrations (up to 2003)—Mauna Loa Observatory, Hawaii, Carbon Dioxide Information Analysis Center, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, http://mercury.ornl.gov/cdiac.

  • Kendrick, J. W. (1961). Productivity trends in the United States. New York: Princeton University Press (for the National Bureau of Economic Research).

    Google Scholar 

  • Khazzoom, J. D. (1980). Economic implications of mandated efficiency standards for household appliances. Energy Journal, 1(4), 21–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khazzoom, J. D. (1987). Energy saving resulting from the adoption of more efficient appliances. Energy Journal, 8(4), 85–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khazzoom, J. D. (1989). Energy savings from more efficient appliances: A rejoinder. Energy Journal, 10(1), 157–166.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kheshgi, H. S., Prince, R. C. & Marland, G. (2000). The potential of biomass fuels in the context of global climate change: Focus on transportation fuels’. Annual Review Energy Environment, 25, 199–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kivel, P. (2004). You call this a democracy? Who benefits, who pays and who really decides. New York: The Apex Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korten, D. (1995). When corporations rule the world. Berrett-Koehler Publishers.

  • Kramer, K. J., Moll, H. C., Nonhebel, S. & Wilting, H. C. (1999). Greenhouse gas emissions related to Dutch food consumption. Energy Policy, 27, 203–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laitner, J. A. (2000). Energy efficiency: Rebounding to a sound analytical perspective. Energy Policy, 28, 471–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane, R. E. (2001). The loss of happiness in market democracies. New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lovins, A. B. (1988). Energy saving resulting from the adoption of more efficient appliances: Another view. Energy Journal, 9(2), 155–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (1991). Dynamic forces in capitalist development: A long-run comparative view, Oxford University Press.

  • Mander, J. (1978). Four arguments for the elimination of television, Harper Perennial.

  • Marland, G., Boden, T. A., & Andres, R. J. (2002). Global, regional, and national fossil fuel CO2 emissions (up to 2002), Carbon Dioxide Information Analysis Center, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, http://mercury.ornl.gov/cdiac.

  • McDonough, W., & Braungart, M. (2002). Cradle to cradle: Remaking the way we make things. North Point Press.

  • McKeown, T. (1988). The origins of human disease. New York: Basil Blackwell, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meadows, D., Randers, J. & Meadows, D. (2004). Limits to growth the 30-year update. White River Junction, Vermont: Chelsea Green Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers, D. G., & Diener, E. (1996). The pursuit of happiness. Scientific American, 274(5), 70–72.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Myers, N., & Kent, J. (2001). Perverse subsidies: How misused tax dollars harm the environment and the economy. Washington, DC: Island Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers, N. (2003). Consumption: Challenge to sustainable development. Science, 276, 53–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nakicenovic, N. (1996). Freeing energy from carbon. Daedalus, 125(3), 95–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nakicenovic, N., & Gruebler, A. (1993). Energy conversion, conservation, and efficiency, chapter 2. Energy, 18(5), 421–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nakicenovic, N., Gruebler, A. & McDonald, A. (1998). Global energy perspective. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, D. L, & Cox, M. M. (2005). Lehninger principles of biochemistry (4th ed.). New York: W.H. Freeman and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Connor, M. (1994). Entropy, liberty, and catastrophe: The physics and metaphysics of waste disposal, In P. Burley & J. Foster (Eds.), Economics and thermodynamics: New perspectives on economic analysis. Boston, Mass: Kluwer, pp. 119–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD/IEA. (2004). 30 Years of energy use in IEA countries. Paris, France: International Energy Agency (IEA).

  • O’Neill, B. C., MacKellar, F. L. & Lutz, W. (2001). Population and climate change. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oswald, A. J. (1997). Happiness and economic performance. Economic Journal, 107(445), 1815–1831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pimentel, D., & Pimentel, M. (1996). Food, energy, and society. Boulder, Colorado: University of Colorado Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett, L. H. (1994). Desired fertility and the impact of population policies. Population and Development Review, 20(1), 1–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rees, W. E., & Wackernagel, M. (1995). Our ecological footprint: Reducing environmental impact on the earth. Gabriola Island, British Columbia, Canada: New Society Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romm, J. J., & Curtis, C. B. (1996). Mideast oil forever? Atlantic Monthly, 277(4), 57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roy, J. (2000). The rebound effect: Some empirical evidence from india. Energy Policy, 28, 433–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruth, M. (1993). Integrating economics, ecology and thermodynamics. Dortrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruth, M. (1995). Information, order and knowledge in economic and ecological systems: Implications for material and energy use. Ecological Economics, 13, 99–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryerson, W.N., (1995). Sixteen myths about population. Focus, 5(1), Population Media Center, http://www.populationmedia.org/issues/sixteen_myths/myths.html.

  • Salter, W. E. G. (1960). Productivity and technical change. London, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A., & Nordhaus, W. D. (1989). Economics, 13th ed. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanne, C. (2000). Dealing with environmental savings in a dynamical economy—how to stop chasing your tail in the pursuit of sustainability. Energy Policy, 28, 487–495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saunders, H. D. (1992). The Khazzoom-Brookes postulate and Neoclassical growth. Energy Journal, 13(4), 131–148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saunders, H. D. (2000). A view from the macro side: Rebound, backfire, and Khazzoom-Brookes. Energy Policy, 28, 439–449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schipper, L., & Grubb, M. (2000). On the rebound? Feedback between energy intensities and energy uses in IEA countries. Energy Policy, 28, 367–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schor, J. B. (2005). Sustainable consumption and worktime reduction. Journal of Industrial Ecology, 9(1–2), 37–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schor, J. B. (1992). The overworked American: The unexpected decline of leisure time. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schurr, S. (1982). Energy efficiency and productive efficiency: Some thoughts based on american experience. Energy Journal, 3(3), 3–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1934). The theory of economic development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sieferle, R. P. (2004). Sustainability in a world history perspective, In B. Benzing & B. Hermann (Eds.), Exploitation and overexploitation in societies past and present. Muenster: Lit Verlag, pp. 123–141.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. L. (1996). The ultimate resource 2. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(August), 312–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stockhammer, E., Hochreiter, H., Obermayr, B., & Steiner, K. (1997). The Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare (ISEW) as an alternative to GDP in measuring economic welfare. The results of the Austrian ISEW calculation 1955–1992. Ecological Economics, 21(1), 19–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tainter, J. A. (1988). The collapse of complex societies. Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • The Population Council. (1992). Future population growth and global warming. In Population, environment, and development, Proceedings of the United Nations Expert Group Meeting on Population, Environment, and Development held at the United National Headquarters, 20–24 January 1992, New York, United Nations, pp. 280–285.

  • Trainer, T. (1995). The conserver society: Alternatives for sustainability. London, UK: Zed Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA). (2005). National Agricultural Statistics Service, Crops by State, http://usda.mannlib.cornell.edu/data-sets/crops/95111/.

  • U.S. Department of Energy (DOE). (2003). Energy information administration. Emissions of Greenhouse Gases in the United States 2003, Trends in U.S. Carbon Intensity and Total Greenhouse Gas Intensity, www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/1605/ggrpt/trends.html.

  • U.S. Department of Energy (DOE). (2004). Energy information administration. Energy Overview, http://www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/mer/overview.html.

  • U.S. Office of Management and Budget (OMB). (2004). Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 2004, Historical Tables, Table 10.1, pp. 182–183, http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget.

  • Vollebergh, H. R. J., & Kemfert, C. (2005). The role of technological change for a sustainable development. Ecological Economics, 54, 133–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Weizsacker, E., Lovins, A. B., & Lovins, L. H. (1998). Factor four: Doubling wealth—halfing resource use. London: Earthscan Publications Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weeks, J., (1992). How to influence fertility: The experience so far. In L. Grant (Ed.), Elephants in the Volkswagen: Facing the tough questions about our overcrowded country (pp. 178–196), Chapter 15. New York: W.H. Freeman.

  • Williams, E., Ayres, R. U., & Heller, M. (2002). The 1.7 kilogram microchip: Energy and material use in the production of semiconductor devices. Environmental Science and Technology, 36(24), 5504–5510.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, E. (2004). Energy intensity of computer manufacturing: Hybrid assessment combining process and economic input-output methods. Environmental Science and Technology, 38(22), 6166–6174.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, R. (2004). A short history of progress. New York: Carroll and Graf Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael H. Huesemann.

Additional information

Readers should send their comments on this paper to BhaskarNath@aol.com within 3 months of publication of this issue.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Huesemann, M.H., Huesemann, J.A. Will progress in science and technology avert or accelerate global collapse? A critical analysis and policy recommendations. Environ Dev Sustain 10, 787–825 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-007-9085-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-007-9085-4

Keywords

Navigation