Skip to main content
Log in

Explicit inflation targets and central bank independence: friends or foes?

  • Published:
Economic Change and Restructuring Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper studies the relationship between two institutional innovations in monetary policy of the past few decades: central bank independence (CBI) and explicit inflation targeting (EIT). The aim is to make inferences about the optimal institutional design of monetary policy, and the right sequencing of policy reform. Our reduced-form model unifies several approaches in the literature, and offers three novel institutional findings (that we square with existing empirical evidence). First, instrument-CBI is a complement to EIT, whereas goal-CBI acts as a strategic substitute for EIT in ensuring low inflation and policy credibility. Second, out of these two ‘commitment technologies,’ EIT is shown to be socially superior to goal-CBI. Third and controversially, countries that first implement goal-CBI are then less likely to adopt the desirable EIT regime. This is because independent central bankers may have less need to do so (their independence partly substitutes for EIT), as well as less willingness to do so (due to a higher degree of accountability associated with a transparently legislated target). Our analysis therefore implies that developing and emerging market countries should go down the New Zealand route—legislate EIT together with instrument-CBI, but stay clear of goal-CBI. Unfortunately, many transition countries have followed the opposite Fed/Bundesbank route, which we show may have adverse welfare consequences through several channels.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On CBI see McCallum (1995), Fuhrer (1997), Posen (1998), Forder (1998a), Jordan (1999), Lippi (1999), and Hayo and Hefeker (2002). On the theory of EIT see Bernanke et al. (1999, 2002), Bernanke (2003), Cecchetti (2003), McCallum (2003), Goodfriend (2003), Kohn (2003), Friedman (2004), Mishkin (2004), and the papers in Bernanke and Woodford (2005). On the empirics of EIT see the references in Sect. 4.

  2. This is perhaps unsurprising—countries are commonly viewed as either inflation targeters or non-targeters, so there is not enough variation in the EIT variable to perform empirical testing. The papers that have attempted to test the effects of EIT using a dummy for EIT, e.g. Ball and Sheridan (2003), have been criticized precisely on this point: Gertler (2003). This is because many countries pursue an inflation target implicitly—including the US, see Goodfriend (2003), or the Bundesbank and the Swiss National Bank in the 1980s, see Bernanke et al. (1999).

  3. Out of the three papers we depict the latter due to the largest sample. This finding can be viewed as robust as it has been found in variety of studies using differently constructed indices for different countries and different periods.

  4. To document this claim from a different angle, the correlation between instrument-CBI and goal-CBI among the 22 transition countries in Fry et al. (2000) is −0.34.

  5. To demonstrate, the survey by Blinder (2000) shows that CBI (without the goal vs. instrument distinction) is still perceived by central bankers and academics as the most important institutional feature of monetary policy in terms of achieving credibility.

  6. The emphasis is however not so much on the details (providing information about shocks and forecasts which has been the focus of most of the literature) but in clarifying what the policy goals are. The need for this sort of communication is reflected in Cecchetti’s (2003) plea in the introduction. The fact that there may be room for improvement is implied by e.g. Goodfriend (2003) who describes the ‘don’t ask, don’t tell’ situation in the US of the early 2000s: ‘Congress doesn’t ask the Fed whether it places a priority on low inflation, and the Fed does not say whether it has such priority’.

  7. An earlier version of the paper featured these aspects but as the contribution was marginal they have been left out.

  8. For the responsible/ambitious terminology see e.g. Faust and Svensson (2001). Government's ambition may be due to re-election attempts in the presence of naïve voters, lobby groups, unions etc; and/or due to the drivers of long-term fiscal stress such as unaffordable welfare/health/pension schemes in the presence of an aging population, high debt, or liabilities implied by public guarantees for financial institutions.

  9. We will abstract from discounting of the central bank and the public for parsimony without affecting our conclusions.

  10. This is in line with models of ‘rational inattention’ (Sims 2003; Reis 2006). We could also incorporate public’s inflation aversion, but follow Backus and Driffill (1985) and disregard it to keep the intuition comparable to standard rational expectations.

  11. In Geraats (2002) goal-TR (referred to as ‘political’ transparency) has three elements, namely ‘formal objectives’, ‘quantitative targets’, and ‘institutional arrangements’. All three are officially grounded in the legal framework of monetary policy (the Central Bank Act, the Statutes etc).

  12. Assuming no punishment for deflation is a technical assumption without loss of generality as neither player has an incentive to choose negative inflation levels in our model.

  13. The literature has often treated AC and goal-TR as synonymous, as they go hand in hand in the real world (Svensson 1999; Mishkin 2004). While this is justified for modelling purposes it may have undesirable consequences: indices of these institutional features include criteria that refer to the other variable. Therefore, we prefer to postulate them separately. Further, it should be noted that real world EIT has a number of additional features other than AC and goal-TR. Nevertheless, as these two pivotal features most affect the incentives of the policymakers and steady-state outcomes, we focus on them.

  14. Arguably, in young democracies the effectiveness of the public’s monitoring may only be improving over time. This could be modelled by obtaining a noisy signal rather than a fully informative one, but we will not pursue this avenue.

  15. There is a growing literature on ‘inflation culture’ that shows that the degree of goal-CBI is driven by various long-run factors, for example the public’s attitudes towards inflation and/or inequality: see Posen (1995), Hayo (1998), and de Jong (2002), and cannot be changed readily.

  16. Since these are one-off decisions we will drop the time subscript on CBI, TR, and AC (except in an overriding situation).

  17. In terms of the small monitoring cost assumption, \( m(\mu ) \le \bar{m}(\bar{\mu }) \), obtaining information has arguably become much more affordable in the era of internet and far reaching media. Alternatively, unlike the inflation and output gap costs that are borne by every member of the society the monitoring cost may be shared. Once the signal is ‘purchased’ by one individual it may be passed onto others with little additional cost. In terms of the imperfect reputation assumption, \( \theta^{e} < 1 \), can best be supported by the length of time that was needed for central banks to re-establish their credibility in the 1980s and 1990s, after the inflationary excesses of the 1970s. Section 5 has more discussion of this.

  18. The appropriate threshold monitoring cost, \( \bar{\mu } \), is now lower due to the inflation reducing effect of goal-TR, but the derivation of (11) implies that a sufficiently low positive level exists.

  19. As possible examples, one can think of the Federal Reserve, the Bundesbank, and the Swiss National Bank.

  20. The undesirable effect of imperfect reputation and/or lacking credibility on policy outcomes and their positive relationship seem uncontroversial, similarly to the gradual reduction of monitoring costs. The effect of the public’s monitoring on the government’s overriding incentives is intuitive.

  21. It should be noted that valid concerns have been expressed over some of these findings and approaches, see Forder (2000). The mixed evidence of the effect of CBI in the post-EIT era found by e.g. Fuhrer (1997), combined with strong evidence of positive CBI effects in the pre-EIT era, is consistent with our findings. It can be explained by the substitutability of goal-CBI and EIT derived in our model.

  22. For completeness, let us mention that in addition to the long-run effects of EIT the literature has identified a number of short-run stabilization effects of EIT. These regard primarily the anchoring effect, e.g. Levin et al. (2004), Kuttner and Posen (1999), Gürkaynak et al. (2005), or Libich (2008), and the effect on the volatility of nominal interest rates, e.g. Siklos (2004), Neumann and von Hagen (2002), or Eijffinger and Geraats (2004).

  23. In terms of (ii), Fry et al. (2000) show that out of the maximum rating of 10, average economic-TR scores for industrial, emerging and developing countries are 6.9, 5.7, and 5.1 respectively. Nevertheless, the data from transition and developing countries, using this index, support all the main conclusions of our analysis. First, EIT (TR and AC) are found to reduce inflation. Second, the negative correlation between goal-CBI and AC procedures is present in both groups.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Querubin P, Robinson JA (2008) When does policy reform work—the case of central bank independence. Brookings Papers Econ Activity 1:351–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Summers LH (1993) Central bank independence and macroeconomic performance: some comparative evidence. J Money Credit Bank 25:151–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus D, Driffill J (1985) Rational expectations and policy credibility following a change in regime. Rev Econ Stud 52:211–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball L, Sheridan N (2003) Does inflation targeting matter? International Monetary Fund IMF working papers: 03/129

  • Barro RJ, Gordon DB (1983) Rules, discretion and reputation in a model of monetary policy. J Monetary Econ 12:101–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke BS (2003) Perspective on inflation targeting. Remarks at the annual Washington policy conference of the National Association of Business Economists, Washington, DC

  • Bernanke BS, Woodford M (2005) The inflation-targeting debate. NBER studies in business cycles, vol 32. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, ix, 458

  • Bernanke BS, Laubach T, Mishkin FS, Posen A (1999) Inflation targeting: lessons from the international experience. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ (2008) The state of macro. NBER working paper 14259

  • Blejer MI et al (2002) Inflation Targeting in the context of Imf-supported adjustment programs. In: Loayza N, Soto N (eds) Inflation targeting: design, performance, challenges. Series on central banking, analysis, and economic policies, vol 5. Central Bank of Chile, Santiago, pp 439–63

  • Blinder AS (2000) Central-bank credibility: why do we care? How do we build it? Am Econ Rev 90:1421–1431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briault C, Haldane A, King M (1997) Independence and accountability. In: Kuroda I (ed) Towards more effective monetary policy. Macmillan Press in association with Bank of Japan, London, pp 299–326

  • Cecchetti SG (2003) The pitfalls in the practice of inflation targeting. Occas Essays Curr Policy Issues 28

  • Chortareas G, Stasavage D, Sterne G (2002) Does it pay to be transparent? International evidence from central bank forecasts. Fed Reserv Bank St. Louis Rev 84:99–117

    Google Scholar 

  • Corbo V, Landerretche O, Schmidt-Hebbel K (2001) Assessing inflation targeting after a decade of world experience. Int J Finance Econ 6:343–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman A, Meltzer AH (1986) A theory of ambiguity, credibility, and inflation under discretion and asymmetric information. Econometrica 54:1099–1128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman A, Webb SB, Neyapti B (1992) Measuring the independence of central banks and its effect on policy outcomes. World Bank Econ Rev 6:353–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Haan J, Amtenbrink F, Eijffinger SCW (1999) Accountability of central banks: aspects and quantification. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Q Rev 52:169–193

    Google Scholar 

  • de Jong E (2002) Why are price stability and statutory independence of central banks negatively correlated? The role of culture. Eur J Polit Econ 18:675–694

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debelle G (1997) Inflation targeting in practice. International Monetary Fund IMF working papers: 97/35

  • Debelle G, Fischer S (1994) How independent should a central bank be? In: Goals, guidelines, and constraints facing monetary policymakers: FRB of Boston, conference series no. 38

  • Demertzis M, Hughes Hallett A (2007) Central bank transparency in theory and practice. J Macroecon 29(4):760–789

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eggertsson GB, Le Borgne E (2003) A political agency theory of central bank independence. International Monetary Fund IMF working papers: 03/144

  • Eijffinger SCW, Geraats PM (2004) Does central bank transparency reduce interest rates? Available at: http://www.econ.cam.ac.uk/faculty/geraats/tpintrate.pdf

  • Eijffinger SCW, Geraats PM (2006) How transparent are central banks? Eur J Polit Econ 22(1):1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eijffinger S, Schaling E (1993) Central bank independence in twelve industrial countries. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Q Rev 0:49–89

    Google Scholar 

  • Eijffinger S, Schaling E, Hoeberichts M (1998) Central bank independence: a sensitivity analysis. Eur J Polit Econ 14:73–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eijffinger SCW, Hoeberichts M, Schaling E (2000) A theory of central bank accountability. CEPR Discussion Papers 2354

  • Faust J, Svensson LEO (2001) Transparency and credibility: monetary policy with unobservable goals. Int Econ Rev 42:369–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faust J, Svensson LEO (2002) The equilibrium degree of transparency and control in monetary policy. J Money Credit Bank 34:520–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feige EL, Pearce DK (1976) Economically rational expectations: are innovations in the rate of inflation independent of innovations in measures of monetary and fiscal policy? J Polit Econ 84(3):499–522

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer S (1990) Rules versus discretion in monetary policy. In: Friedman B, Hahn F (eds) Handbook of monetary economics, vol 2. Oxford and Tokyo: North-Holland; distributed in the U.S. and Canada by Elsevier, New York, pp 1155–1184

  • Forder J (1998a) The case for an independent european central bank: a reassessment of evidence and sources. Eur J Polit Econ 14:53–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forder J (1998b) Central bank independence—conceptual clarifications and interim assessment. Oxford Econ Papers 50(3):307–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forder J (2000) Central bank independence and credibility: is there a shred of evidence? Int Finance 3(1):167–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman BM (2004) Why the federal reserve should not adopt inflation targeting. Int Finance 7:129–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fry M, Julius D, Mahadeva L, Roger S, Sterne G (2000) Key issues in the choice of a monetary policy framework. In: Mahadeva L, Sterne G (eds) Monetary frameworks in a global context. Routledge, London

  • Fuhrer JC (1997) Central bank independence and inflation targeting: monetary policy paradigms for the next millenium? N Engl Econ Rev (Federal Reserve Bank of Boston) 19–36

  • Geraats PM (2001) Why adopt transparency? The publication of central bank forecasts, European Central Bank working paper series, 41

  • Geraats PM (2002) Central bank transparency. Econ J 112:F532–F565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gertler M (2003) Monetary policy and uncertainty: adapting to a changing economy. Symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. Jackson Hole, Wyoming

  • Goodfriend M (2003) Inflation targeting in the United States? National Bureau of Economic Research Inc NBER working papers, 9981

  • Grilli V, Masciandaro D, Tabellini G (1991) Political and monetary institutions and public financial policies in the industrial countries. Economic policy: a European Forum, pp 341–392

  • Gürkaynak RS, Sack B, Swanson E (2005) The sensitivity of long-term interest rates to economic news: evidence and implications for macroeconomic models. Am Econ Rev 95:425–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayo B (1998) Inflation culture, central bank independence and price stability. Eur J Polit Econ 14:241–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayo B, Hefeker C (2002) Reconsidering central bank independence. Eur J Polit Econ 18:653–674

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes Hallett A, Weymark DN (2004) Independent monetary policies and social equity. Econ Lett 85:103–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes Hallett A, Weymark DN (2005) Independence before conservatism: transparency, politics and central bank design. German Econ Rev 6:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes Hallett A, Di Bartolomeo G, Acocella N (2008) When can central banks anchor expectations? Policy Commun Control. CEPR discussion paper 7078

  • Hyvonen M (2004) Inflation convergence across countries. Reserve Bank of Australia Discussion Paper 2004-04

  • Imperato I (2002) A case for transparency in monetary policy. Available at http://www.dt.tesoro.it/Aree-Docum/Relazioni-/Working-Pa/CB-monitoring-finale.pdf

  • Jordan TJ (1999) Central bank independence and the sacrifice ratio. Eur J Polit Econ 15:229–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King M (1998) The inflation target five years on. London School of Economics, 99

  • Kohn DL (2003) Remarks at the 28th annual policy conference: inflation targeting: prospects and problems. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, St. Louis, Missouri

  • Kuttner KN, Posen AS (1999) Does talk matter after all? Inflation targeting and Central bank behavior. Staff reports 88, Federal Reserve Bank of New York

  • Kydland FE, Prescott EC (1977) Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. J Polit Econ 85:473–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeper EM (1991) Equilibria under ‘active’ and ‘passive’ monetary and fiscal policies. J Monetary Econ 27(1):129–147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levin AT, Natalucci FM, Piger JM (2004) The macroeconomic effects of inflation targeting. Federal Reserve Bank St. Louis Rev 86:51–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Libich J (2008) A note on the anchoring effect of explicit inflation targets. Macroecon Dyn (forthcoming)

  • Lippi F (1999) Central bank independence, targets and credibility: political and economic aspects of delegation arrangements for monetary policy. Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton, Mass.: Elgar; distributed by American International Distribution Corporation Williston Vt

  • Masson PR, Savastano MA, Sharma S (1997) The scope for inflation targeting in developing countries. International Monetary Fund IMF working papers 97/130

  • McCallum BT (1995) Two fallacies concerning central-bank independence. Am Econ Rev 85:207–211

    Google Scholar 

  • McCallum BT (2003) Inflation targeting for the United States. Shadow Open Market Committee, available at http://www.somc.rochester.edu/May03/McCallum.pdf

  • Mishkin FS (2004) Why the federal reserve should adopt inflation targeting. Int Finance 7:117–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin FS (2010) The fed must adopt an inflation target. Financ Times

  • Neumann MJM, von Hagen J (2002) Does inflation targeting matter? Federal Reserve Bank St. Louis Rev 84:127–148

    Google Scholar 

  • Posen A (1995) Is central bank independence the result of effective opposition to inflation? Evidence of endogenous monetary policy institutions. NBER macroeconomics annual

  • Posen A (1998) Central bank independence and disinflationary credibility: a missing link? Oxford Econ Papers 50:335–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reis R (2006) Inattentive consumers. J Monetary Econ 53(8):1761–1800

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff K (1985) The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Q J Econ 100:1169–1189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent TJ, Wallace N (1981) Some unpleasant monetarist arithmetic. Federal Reserve Bank Minneapolis Q Rev 5:1–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Schaling E, Nolan C (1998) Monetary policy uncertainty and inflation: the role of central bank accountability. De Econ 146:585–602

    Google Scholar 

  • Siklos PL (2004) Central bank behavior, the institutional framework, and policy regimes: inflation versus noninflation targeting countries. Contemp Econ Policy 22:331–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sims CA (2003) Implications of rational inattention. J Monetary Econ 50(3):665–690

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singleton J, Grimes A, Hawke G, Holmes F (2007) Innovation and independence: The Reserve Bank of New Zealand 1973–2004. Auckland University Press, Auckland (forthcoming)

  • Sousa P (2002) Central bank independence and democratic accountability. Mimeo, Portucalense University, available at http://www.univ-orleans.fr/deg/GDRecomofi/Activ/doclyon/desousa.pdf

  • Svensson LEO (1997a) Inflation forecast targeting: implementing and monitoring inflation targets. Eur Econ Rev 41:1111–1146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson LEO (1997b) Optimal inflation targets, “conservative” central banks, and linear inflation contracts. Am Econ Rev 87:98–114

    Google Scholar 

  • Svensson LEO (1999) Inflation targeting as a monetary policy rule. J Monetary Econ 43:607–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen J (1954) Centralization and decentralization in economic policy. Amsterdam

  • Walsh CE (1995) Optimal contracts for central bankers. Am Econ Rev 85:150–167

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh CE (2009) Inflation targeting: what have we learned? Int Finance 12(2):195–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Willard L (2006) Does inflation targeting matter: a reassessment. CEPS WP 120, Princeton University

  • Wu T (2004) Does inflation targeting reduce inflation? An analysis for the Oecd industrial countries. Banco Central do Brazil Working Paper 83

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Don Brash, Andrew Haldane, Jonathan Kearns, Glenn Otto, Jeff Sheen, and the participants of several conferences and seminars for their valuable comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jan Libich.

Additional information

This is a significantly revised version of ‘Central Bank Independence, Accountability, and Transparency: Complements or Strategic Substitutes?’

Appendices

Appendix 1: Proof of Proposition 1

As overriding is not observable the public forms an expectation of it, \( R_{t}^{e} \), and sets inflation expectations rationally based on (9)

$$ (\pi_{t}^{e} )^{ * } = \bar{\pi } + \frac{{\lambda^{g} }}{2\omega }\left[ {1 - CBI(1 - R_{t}^{e} )} \right] $$
(19)

Moving forward let us examine the overriding choice. Under M t  = 1 the public knows the true \( g_{t}^{T} \), i.e. has full information about the opponents’ preferences and can thus perfectly anticipate overriding, \( (R_{t}^{e} )^{ * } = R_{t} \). Using this constraint with (2), (9) and (19) yields

$$ \frac{{\partial u^{{g^{W} }} }}{\partial R} = - \frac{{\lambda^{g} CBI}}{2\omega }\left[ {1 - CBI(1 - R_{t} )} \right] < 0 $$
(20)

This implies that \( R_{t}^{ * } = 0 \), \( \forall g^{T} \). The public therefore sets \( (R_{t}^{e} )^{ * } = 0 \) in (19), leading to \( x_{t}^{ * } = 0 \) from (1). \( \square \)

Appendix 2: CBI index (Sousa 2002)

 

Criteria

Points

Personal independence

 1. Appointment of the central bank board members

1.00

 2. Mandate duration of more than half of the central bank board members

1.00

 3. Policymaker (or other fiscal branches representatives) participation at central bank meetings, where monetary decisions are taken

1.00

Political independence

 4. Ultimate responsibility and authority on monetary policy decisions

1.00

 5. Price stability

1.00

 6. Banking supervision

1.00

 7. Monetary policy instruments

1.00

Economic and financial independence

 8. Policymaker financing

1.00

 9. Ownership of the central bank’s (equity) capital

1.00

Appendix 3: AC index (Sousa 2002)

Criteria and methodology of this index is adopted from de Haan et al. (1999). We only use the ‘final responsibility’ component that we believe best proxies the degree of EIT.

 

Criteria

Points

Final responsibility

 1. Is the central bank subject of monitoring by Parliament?

1.00

 2. Has the policymaker (or Parliament) the right to give instruction?

1.00

 3. Is there some kind of review in the procedure to apply the override mechanism?

1.00

 4. Has central bank possibility for an appeal in case of an instruction?

1.00

 5. Can the central bank law be changed by a simple majority in Parliament?

1.00

 6. Is past performance a ground for dismissal of a central bank governor?

1.00

Appendix 4: Goal-CBI index (Briault et al. 1997)

 

1. Whether the statutes of the central bank make it independent of the government

2.00

2. Whether more than half the appointments to the central bank board are made independently of the government

2.00

3. Whether there are government officials on the board

2.00

4. Whether the central bank does in practice set its own goals (for example, monetary or inflation targets).

2.00

Appendix 5: TR index (Eijffinger and Geraats 2006)

 

1. Political

 (a) Formal objectives

1.00

 (b) Quantitative targets

1.00

 (c) Institutional arrangements

1.00

2. Economic

 (a) Economic data

1.00

 (b) Policy models

1.00

 (c) Central bank forecasts

1.00

3. Procedural

 (a) Explicit strategy

1.00

 (b) Minutes

1.00

 (c) Voting records

1.00

4. Policy

 (a) Prompt announcement

1.00

 (b) Policy explanation

1.00

 (c) Policy inclination

1.00

5. Operational

 (a) Control errors

1.00

 (b) Transmission disturbances

1.00

 (c) Evaluation policy outcome

1.00

Appendix 6: Evaluation table

 

Index

CBI Sousa (2002)a

AC Sousa (2002)a

TR Eijffinger and Geraats (2006) for 1998

Goal-CBI Briault et al. (1997)

Country

Personal

Political

Economic and financial

Totalb

Final responsibility

Political

Economic

Procedural

Policy

Operational

Total

Total

1

Argentina

1.25

2.83

1.00

5.08

2

       

2

Australia

0.50

2.16

0.00

2.66

5

3

1

1

1.5

1.5

8

2

3

Austria

1.66

3.16

1.00

5.82

1

       

4

Belgium

1.75

1.50

0.00

3.25

4

       

5

Canada

0.50

1.83

0.00

2.33

4

3

2.5

1

2

2

10.5

2

6

Chile

2.00

1.83

1.00

4.83

3

       

7

Czech Republic

1.58

3.16

1.00

5.74

2

       

8

Denmark

2.16

2.83

0.00

4.99

2

       

9

EMU—ECB

2.50

3.66

1.00

7.16

1

       

10

England

1.00

2.66

0.00

3.66

4

3

1.5

3

1.5

2

11

1

11

Finland

2.50

3.66

1.00

7.16

2

       

12

France

1.50

3.16

1.00

5.66

2

       

13

Germany

1.50

3.16

1.00

5.66

2

1c

1c

1c

2c

1c

6c

6

14

Greece

1.91

3.16

1.00

6.07

1

       

15

Hungary

1.91

3.66

1.00

6.57

2

       

16

Iceland

1.75

3.33

0.00

5.08

4

       

17

Ireland

1.00

3.16

1.00

5.16

2

       

18

Italy

2.16

3.16

1.00

6.32

1

       

19

Japan

0.75

3.66

0.00

4.41

3

1.5

1

2

1.5

2

8

4

20

Korea

0.75

2.16

0.00

2.91

4

       

21

Luxemburg

1.25

3.16

1.00

5.41

2

       

22

Mexico

1.83

2.33

0.00

4.16

2

       

23

Netherlands

2.41

3.16

0.00

5.57

2

       

24

New Zealand

1.83

2.16

1.00

4.99

4

3

2.5

3

1

1

10.5

3

25

Norway

1.58

1.83

0.00

3.41

5

       

26

Poland

1.25

2.16

0.00

3.41

3

       

27

Portugal

1.50

3.16

1.00

5.66

1

       

28

Slovakia

1.00

3.50

1.00

5.50

1

       

29

Spain

0.75

3.16

1.00

4.91

2

       

30

Sweden

2.75

3.16

1.00

6.91

1

2

1.5

2

1.5

2

9

2

31

Switzerland

2.08

3.33

1.00

6.41

2

1

1

1

2

1

6

6

32

Turkey

1.66

2.83

0.00

4.49

3

       

33

USA

2.00

1.83

0.00

3.83

2

1

2.5

2

1.5

1.5

8.5

4

  1. aAssessment is based on situation in January 2002
  2. bExcludes aspect 9 due to missing observations
  3. cEijffinger and Geraats (2006) do not provide a value for the Bundesbank for the year 1998. The literature agrees that Bundesbank’s practices were very similar to the Swiss National Bank’s (see e.g. Bernanke et al. 1999) and we indeed find all the two countries’ criteria scores to coincide. This is further supported by the fact that in Sousa (2002) and Fry et al. (2000) the scores of the two central banks are equal (in the latter index in terms of goal-TR)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Hallett, A.H., Libich, J. Explicit inflation targets and central bank independence: friends or foes?. Econ Change Restruct 45, 271–297 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-011-9118-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-011-9118-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation