Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Abatement Technology and the Environment–Growth Nexus with Education

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The present paper adopts a Yaari (Rev Econ Stud 32:137–150, 1965) and Blanchard (J Polit Econ 93(2):223–247, 1985) overlapping generations model with Lucas’s (J Monet Econ 22(1):3–42, 1988) human capital accumulation in order to examine how environmental taxation influences growth. It challenges conventional result that tighter environmental tax has either no long term effect at all, or has a positive long term effect. In the case of Cobb–Douglas production functions and logarithmic utilities, this paper demonstrates that the technology used in the abatement sector determines the existence and direction of the growth effect. In the case of output taxation, if the abatement sector is relatively more (respectively less) intensive in human capital than the final output sector, tighter environmental tax increases (resp. reduces) growth in the long term. This result always holds true for finite life expectancy but for infinite life expectancy it only holds true when the labour supply is endogenous. The transitional impact of tighter environmental policy is also investigated. We find that the magnitude of the short term effects of environmental taxation varies according to the technology used in the abatement and final output sectors, and that there is a reverse trade-off between the short and the long term effects.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development and the Statistical Office of the European Commission (OECD/Eurostat 1999, p. 9), define eco-industry as the set of “(\(\ldots \)) activities which produce goods and services to measure, prevent, limit, minimise or correct environmental damage to water, air, and soil, as well as problems related to waste, noise and eco-systems. These include cleaner technologies, products and services which reduce environmental risk and minimize pollution and resource use”. Nimubona and Sinclair-Desgagné (2011) reported that the eco-industry represents 1.7 % of employment and 2.2 % of GDP in the European Union and the United States and that it is expected to generate revenue of US$ 800 billion by 2015, making it similar in size to the aerospace and pharmaceutical sectors (see Sinclair-Desgagne 2008, for more data).

  2. Note that in the present paper we do not address how pollution affects health and life expectancy.

  3. For the sake of simplicity, we only take into account the differences in relative factor intensity in the final output and abatement sectors. More complex and more realistic modelling of abatement activities is beyond the scope of this paper.

  4. In the following analysis, we consider that the most relevant case for developed countries is that abatement sectors are more intensive in human capital.

  5. This term is borrowed from the anonymous referee who highlighted this point to me.

  6. We assumed a constant population for simplicity. Considering population growth would not modify our qualitative results. Proof available upon request.

  7. Assuming that \(h(t,t)=\iota H(t)\) with \(\iota \in ]0,1[\) would not modify our qualitative results. Proof available upon request.

  8. We introduce the after-tax interest rate \(r_{n}\) because in Sect. 4 we examine the case where environmental tax is applied to physical capital income. For the moment there is no tax on physical capital income and therefore \(r_{n}=r\) represents the real interest rate.

  9. Each agent concludes a contract with an insurance company that pays him or her an annuity proportional to his or her wealth during life. In exchange, agents transfer their overall wealth on the day they die (see Blanchard and Fisher 1989, pp. 116–117). Assuming imperfect annuity markets (like Heijdra and Mierau 2010) would not modify the qualitative results of our model. Proof available upon request.

  10. See “Appendix A” for further explanations.

  11. From (12), the equalisation of the rates of returns given by Eq. (6) implies that the rate of return to human capital is independent of \(s\) and therefore that all individuals allocate the same effort to schooling: \(u(s,t)=u\).

  12. I thank the co-editor Michael Rauscher who highlighted this point.

  13. The BGP equilibrium we computed has two positive eigenvalues and one negative eigenvalue. Because there are two jump variables \((x\hbox { and }u)\) and one predetermined variable \((z)\), the equilibrium is locally saddle-point stable. Because of the 3 \(\times \) 3 matrix, the analytical demonstration of the saddle-path stability is cumbersome and is beyond the scope of this paper.

  14. The results are robust to alternative values of \(\varepsilon \).

  15. That enables us to draw on the same graph the different cases: abatement sector more intensive in human capital \((\varepsilon <\alpha )\), abatement sector more intensive in physical capital \((\varepsilon >\alpha )\), same technology \((\varepsilon =\alpha )\).

  16. Note that we find a trade-off between the short and long terms when the environmental tax stimulus is less important and the difference in factor intensity is high enough \((\varepsilon \gg \alpha )\). Indeed, in this case an increase in abatement production due to a tighter environmental tax reinforces the positive pressure on the interest rate.

  17. These equations are derived in a similar way to Eqs. (19)–(21).

  18. Even in the most disadvantageous case, namely when the abatement sector uses no human capital at all, the initial drop in the interest rate would be smaller but would remain negative (see Eq. 25a for the limit case \(\varepsilon =0\)). There is no reallocation of human capital from the output sector to the abatement sector however because the returns to physical capital investment are smaller than those to education at the impact, agents are incited to invest more in human capital accumulation. The process is made easier because physical capital moves from the output sector to the abatement sector and because the abatement sector does not use human capital therefore, human capital is freed from the output sector to be employed in education.

  19. According to Mani et al. (2002), five sectors emerge as dirty industries: Iron and Steel, Non-Ferrous Metals, Industrial Chemicals, Paper and Pulp (341) and Non-Metallic Mineral Products. The authors exclude Petroleum because very few countries are producers. The majority of environmental works that have tested the “pollution haven” hypothesis have calculated the factorial intensity of the highest polluting industries for the US (Cole et al. 2005), Japan (Cole et al. 2006) and China (Cole et al. 2008). These studies have found that the physical to human capital ratio is higher than unity for these nations.

  20. This explanation is borrowed from Heijdra (2009, p. 468).

  21. See the textbook by Barro and Sala-i Martin (1995, p. 184), among others.

  22. Note that \(\frac{1-\tau _{k}}{\Upsilon (\tau _{k})}=\frac{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau _{k})}{1-\alpha +(\alpha -\varepsilon )\tau _{k}}\) and \(\partial \frac{1-\tau _{k}}{\Upsilon (\tau _{k})}/\partial \tau _{k}\le 0\) (it comes directly from \(\partial \frac{1-\tau _{k}}{\Upsilon (\tau _{k})}/\partial \tau _{k}=-\frac{(1-\alpha )(1-\varepsilon )}{\left[ 1-\alpha +(\alpha -\varepsilon )\tau _{k}\right] ^{2}}\le 0,\,\forall (\alpha ,\varepsilon )\in (0,1)\)).

References

  • Barro R, Sala-i Martin X (1995) Economic growth. MacGraw-Hill, New-York

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Fisher S (1989) Lectures on macroeconomics. MIT Press, Cambridge

  • Blanchard OJ (1985) Debt, deficits, and finite horizons. J Polit Econ 93(2):223–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bovenberg A, Van Ewijk C (1997) Progressive taxes, equity, and human capital accumulation in an endogenous growth model with overlapping generations. J Public Econ 64:153–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole MA, Elliott RJR, Shimamoto K (2005) Why the grass is not always greener: the competing effects of environmental regulations and factor intensities on us specialization. Ecol Econ 54(1):95–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole MA, Elliott RJR, Shimamoto K (2006) Globalization, firm-level characteristics and environmental management: a study of Japan. Ecol Econ 59(3):312–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole MA, Elliott RJR, Wu S (2008) Industrial activity and the environment in China: an industry-level analysis. China Econ Rev 19(3):393–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devereux MB, Love DRF (1994) The effects of factor taxation in a two-sector model of endogenous growth. Can J Econ 27(3):509–536

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gradus R, Smulders S (1993) The trade-off between environmental care and long-term growth-pollution in three prototype growth models. J Econ 58(1):25–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimaud A, Tournemaine F (2007) Why can environmental policy tax promote growth through the channel of education? Ecol Econ 62(1):27–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heijdra BJ (2009) Foundations of modern macroeconomics. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Heijdra BJ, Mierau J (2010) Growth effects of consumption and labor-income taxation in an overlapping-generations life-cycle model. Macroecon Dyn 14(Supplement S2):151–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heston A, Summers R, Aten PB (2011) Penn world table version 7.0. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania

  • Hettich F (1998) Growth effects of a revenue-neutral environmental tax reform. J Econ 67(3):287–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennett M, Steenblik R (2005) Environmental goods and services: a synthesis of country studies. OECD Trade and Environment Working Papers 2005/03, OECD

  • Lucas RE Jr (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22(1):3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mani M, Wheeler D, Munasinghe M (2002) In search of pollution havens? Dirty industry in the world economy, 1960–1995, pp 464–477. Elgar reference collection. International Library of Critical Writings in, Economics, vol 141, Unlisted

  • Miller MH, Modigliani F (1961) Dividend policy, growth, and the valuation of shares. J Bus 34(4):411–433

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan CB, Sala-i Martin X (1991) A note on the time-elimination methods for solving recursive dynamic economic models. National Bureau of Economic Research Technical Working Paper 116, Cambridge, MA

  • Mulligan CB, Sala-i Martin X (1993) Transitional dynamics in two-sector models of endogenous growth. Q J Econ 108(3):739–773

  • Nimubona A-D, Sinclair-Desgagné B (2011) Polluters and abaters. Ann Econ Stat 103/104:9–24

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD/Eurostat (1999) The environmental goods and services industry: manual for data collection and analysis. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Pautrel X (2008) Reconsidering the impact of pollution on long-run growth when pollution influences health and agents have a finite-lifetime. Environ Resour Econ 40(1):37–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pautrel X (2009) Pollution and life expectancy: how environmental policy can promote growth. Ecol Econ 68(4):1040–1051

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pautrel X (2012a) Environmental policy, education and growth: a reappraisal when lifetime is finite. Macroecon Dyn 16(5):661–685

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pautrel X (2012b) Pollution, private investment in healthcare, and environmental policy. Scand J Econ 114(2):334–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prescott EC (2004) Why do Americans work so much more than Europeans? Fed Reserve Bank Minneap Q Rev 28(1):2–13

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinclair-Desgagne B (2008) The environmental goods and services industry. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ 2(1):69–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Ewijk C, Van Wijnbergen S (1995) Can abatement overcome the conflict between environment and economic growth? De Econ 143(2):197–216

    Google Scholar 

  • Yaari M (1965) Uncertain lifetime, life insurance and the theory of consumer. Rev Econ Stud 32:137–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xavier Pautrel.

Additional information

The author thank the co-editor Michael Rauscher and two anonymous referees for their remarks. The usual disclaimer applies.

Appendices

Appendix A

In this appendix, we solve the model.

The program of the households is

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{rl} \displaystyle {\max _{c(s,t),l(s,t),a(s,t),h(s,t),u(s,t)}}&{}\displaystyle \int \limits _s^\infty \left[ \log c(s,t)+\xi _{l}\log l(s,t)- \zeta \log S\right] e^{-(\varrho +\beta )(t-s)}dt\\ s.t.&{} \dot{a}(s,t)=\left[ r_{n}+\beta \right] a(s,t) +u(s,t)h(s,t) w(t)-c(s,t)\\ &{}\dot{h}(s,t)=B \left[ 1-u(s,t)-l(s,t)\right] h(s,t)\\ &{} a(s,s)=0\qquad h(s,s)= H(s)>0 \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

The Hamiltonian of the program may be written as

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal {H}&= \log c(s,t)+\xi _{l}\log l(s,t)- \zeta \log S+\pi _{1}(t)\\&\times \left[ \left( r_{n}+\beta \right) a(s,t) +u(s,t)h(s,t) w(t)-c(s,t)\right] \\&+\,\,\pi _{2}(t)B \left[ 1-u(s,t)-l(s,t)\right] h(s,t) \end{aligned}$$

where \(\pi _{1}(t)\) and \(\pi _{2}(t)\) are the co-state variables.

The first-order conditions are

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\displaystyle \partial \mathcal {H}}{\displaystyle \partial c(s,t)}&= 0 \qquad \Rightarrow \qquad \dfrac{1}{c(s,t)}=\pi _{1}(t)\end{aligned}$$
(30)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\displaystyle \partial \mathcal {H}}{\displaystyle \partial u(s,t)}&= 0 \qquad \Rightarrow \qquad \pi _{1}(t)w(t)=\pi _{2}(t)B\end{aligned}$$
(31)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\displaystyle \partial \mathcal {H}}{\displaystyle \partial l(s,t)}&= 0 \qquad \Rightarrow \qquad \dfrac{\xi _{l}}{l(s,t)}=\pi _{2}(t)B h(s,t)\end{aligned}$$
(32)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\displaystyle \partial \mathcal {H}}{\displaystyle \partial a(s,t)}&= -\dot{\pi }_{1}(t)+(\varrho +\beta )\pi _{1}(t) \qquad \Rightarrow \qquad \pi _{1}(t)(r(t)+\beta )=-\dot{\pi }_{1}(t)+(\varrho +\beta )\pi _{1}(t)\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(33)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\displaystyle \partial \mathcal {H}}{\displaystyle \partial h(s,t)}&= -\dot{\pi }_{2}(t)+(\varrho +\beta )\pi _{2}(t) \nonumber \\&\Rightarrow \pi _{1}(t)w(t)u(s,t)+\pi _{2}(t)B (1\!-\!u(s,t)\!-\!l(s,t))=-\dot{\pi }_{2}(t)+(\varrho +\beta )\pi _{2}(t)\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(34)

From (30) and (33), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{c}(s,t)=(r(t)-\varrho )c(s,t) \end{aligned}$$
(4)

Equations (30), (31) and (32) give

$$\begin{aligned} l(s,t)= \dfrac{\xi _{l}c(s,t)}{w(t)h(s,t)} \end{aligned}$$
(35)

From Eq. (33): \(\varrho +\beta =r(t)+\beta +\frac{\dot{\pi }_{1}(t)}{\pi _{1}(t)}\). From Eqs. (31), (33) and (34): \(\varrho +\beta =B (1-l(s,t))+\frac{\dot{\pi }_{2}(t)}{\pi _{2}(t)}\). Equalizing both expression we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{B (1-l(s,t))\pi _{2}(t)+\dot{\pi }_{2}(t)}{\pi _{2}(t)}=\frac{(r(t)+\beta )\pi _{1}(t)+\dot{\pi }_{1}(t)}{\pi _{1}(t)} \end{aligned}$$
(36)

First, this equation means that \(l(s,t)\) is independent from \(s\): \(l(s,t)=l(t)\) defined by Eq. (35). Second, this equation is the “fundamental principle of valuation” (Miller and Modigliani 1961, p. 412) according to which the rate of return on different assets (dividends plus capital gains) must be equal.Footnote 20 \(B (1-l(t))\pi _{2}(t)\) is the dividend on human capital and \((r(t)+\beta )\pi _{1}(t)\) is the dividend on physical capital (or financial assets) valued in terms of utility. The dividend on human capital is explained as follows (see Eq. 34): Investing in one unit of human capital rises the stock of human capital by \(B(1-u-l)\) valued in terms of utility at \(\pi _{2}\) the shadow price of human capital, and increases earnings from production by \(uw\) valued in terms of utility at \(\pi _{1}\) the shadow price of physical capital (or financial assets). Therefore the dividend on human capital is \(B(1-u-l)\pi _{2}+uw\pi _{1}\). Because time must be equally valuable in its two uses (physical capital accumulation and human capital accumulation), we have \( \pi _{1} w=\pi _{2}B\) (see Eq. 31). Therefore, the dividend on human capital is equal to \( B(1-l)\pi _{2}\). Differentiating (31) with respect to time, we obtain \(\frac{\dot{\pi }_{1}(t)}{\pi _{1}(t)}+\frac{\dot{w}(t)}{w(t)}= \frac{\dot{\pi }_{2}(t)}{\pi _{2}(t)}\). Replacing by the expressions of \(\frac{\dot{\pi }_{1}(t)}{\pi _{1}(t)}\) and \(\frac{\dot{\pi }_{2}(t)}{\pi _{2}(t)}\), it gives

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{w}(t)}{w(t)}+B( 1-l(t))=r(t)+\beta \end{aligned}$$

which is an another way to write the fundamental principle of valuation. Because the return to physical capital is independent of \(s\), the return to human capital is also independent of \(s\) and, therefore, agents allocate the same effort to schooling: \(u(s,t)=u(t)\).

Differentiating the expression of aggregate consumption, \(C(t)=\int _{-\infty }^{t}c(s,t)\beta e^{-\beta (t-s)}ds\), with respect to time, using the expression of \(dK/dt,\,d\Omega /dt\) and Eq. (4) we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{C}/C=r-\varrho - \beta \left( \varrho +\beta \right) K/C\end{aligned}$$
(37)

The market clearing condition is written as

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{K}(t)=(1-\tau )Y(t)-C(t) \end{aligned}$$

Recalling that \(\dot{h}(s,t)=B(1-u(t)-l(t))h(s,t)\) and \(h(s,s)= H(s)\), differentiating with respect to time \(H(t)=\int _{-\infty }^t h(s,t) \beta e^{-\beta (t-s)} ds\) gives the aggregate accumulation of human capital:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{H}(t)=B(1-u(t)-l(t)) H(t) \end{aligned}$$
(17)

Finally, from Eq. (6), from the expression of the wage rate (Eq. 13) and the fact that \(\int _{-\infty }^t u(s,t) h(s,t) \beta e^{-\beta (t-s)} ds=u(t)H(t)\) because \(u(s,t)=u(t)\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \dfrac{\dot{u}(t)}{u(t)}=\dfrac{\dot{K}(t)}{K(t)}-\dfrac{\dot{H}(t)}{H(t)}-\alpha ^{-1}\left[ r(t)+\beta -B (1-l(t))\right] \end{aligned}$$

Defining \(x\equiv C/K\) and \(z\equiv H/K\), and using previous results, the dynamical system is summarized by

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{x}/x=\left[ \alpha (1-\tau ) -\Phi (\tau )\right] \Psi (\tau )^{\alpha -1}(z\ u)^{1-\alpha }-\varrho -\beta (\beta +\varrho )x^{-1}+x\end{aligned}$$
(19)
$$\begin{aligned} \dot{z}/z=B\left[ 1-u-l\right] -\Phi (\tau )\Psi (\tau )^{\alpha -1}(z\ u)^{1-\alpha }+x\end{aligned}$$
(20)
$$\begin{aligned} \dot{u}/u=\alpha ^{-1}\left[ B(1-l)-\beta -\alpha (1-\tau )\Psi (\tau )^{\alpha -1}(z\ u)^{1-\alpha } \right] -\dot{z}/z\end{aligned}$$
(21)

Appendix B

1.1 B.1 The Case \(\beta >0\)

From (21), \(\dot{u}=0\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} (z^{\star }\ u^{\star })^{1-\alpha }=\dfrac{\Psi (\tau )^{1-\alpha }}{\alpha (1-\tau )}\left[ B(1-l^{\star })-\beta \right] \end{aligned}$$
(38)

Because \(z^{\star }\ u^{\star }>0\), it implies

$$\begin{aligned} B(1-l^{\star })-\beta >0 \qquad \Rightarrow \qquad B>\beta \end{aligned}$$
(39)

The returns to education in the long term \(B(1-l^{\star })\) net of the probability to die \(\beta \) must be positive in order to incite agents to invest in human capital accumulation, and therefore to have a positive rate of growth along the BGP.

Furthermore, from (19) and (20), \(\dot{x}-\dot{z}=0\) at the steady-state gives (with 38):

$$\begin{aligned} x^{\star }=\dfrac{\beta (\beta +\varrho )}{B u^{\star }- \beta -\varrho } \end{aligned}$$
(40)

Because \(x^{\star }>0\), it is required that

$$\begin{aligned} u^{\star }>\dfrac{\beta +\varrho }{B}\qquad \text{ with }~~B>\beta +\varrho \end{aligned}$$
(41)

\(B>\beta +\varrho \) means that the productivity in education \(B\) must be higher than the subjective discount rate \(\varrho +\beta \) (the rate of time preference plus the instantaneous probability of death) in order to incite agents to give up one unit of consumption today and invest it in education. Conditions (39) and (41) are conventional in the Lucas (1988) human capital accumulation model.Footnote 21 Therefore, \(x^{\star }\ u^{\star }\) is an increasing function of \(u^{\star }\).

Using (23) and (38), we obtain \(l^{\star }=\frac{\xi _{l }\alpha }{(1-\alpha )\Psi (\tau )}\times \frac{ x^{\star }\ u^{\star }}{B(1-l^{\star })-\beta } \) which is a quadratic equation of \(l^{\star }\in [0,1[\) with only one solution verifying \(B(1-u^{\star }-l^{\star })>0\):

$$\begin{aligned} l^{\star }=\dfrac{1}{2}\left( \dfrac{B-\beta -\sqrt{(B-\beta )^{2}-4\frac{\xi _{l }\alpha }{(1-\alpha )\Psi (\tau )}B\ x^{\star }\ u^{\star }}}{B}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(42)

with \(\partial {l^{\star }}/\partial {u^{\star }}>0\) (because \(x^{\star }u^{\star }\) is increasing in \(u^{\star }\) as demonstrated above) and \(\partial {l^{\star }}/\partial {\Psi (\tau )}<0\).

\(\dot{z}=0\) leads to, using (20), (38) and (22):

$$\begin{aligned} x^{\star }=B u^{\star }- \left( 1+\dfrac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\Psi (\tau )\right) \beta + \dfrac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\Psi (\tau )B\left[ 1-l^{\star }\right] \end{aligned}$$
(43)

Equating (40) and (43) enables to express \(u^{\star }\) as the solution of

$$\begin{aligned} \Gamma (u,\tau )\equiv B u - \beta + \dfrac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\Psi (\tau )\left( B\left( 1-l^{\star }\right) -\beta \right) -\dfrac{\beta (\beta +\varrho )}{B u- \beta -\varrho } =0 \end{aligned}$$

with \(l^{\star }\) defined by Eq. (42), and \(\Gamma _{u}(u,\tau )>0\) and \(\Gamma _{\Psi (\tau )}(u,\tau )>0\) because \(\Gamma _{u}(u,\tau )=B+\frac{B\beta (\beta +\varrho )}{(Bu-\beta -\varrho )^{2}}+\xi _{l} \frac{\frac{B\beta (\beta +\varrho )^{2}}{(Bu-\beta -\varrho )^{2}}}{\sqrt{(B-\beta )^{2}-\frac{4 \alpha \xi _{l}}{(1-\alpha )\Psi (\tau )} B\ x^{\star }u^{\star }}}>0 \). From (41), \(u^{\star }\in ](\beta +\varrho )/B,1[\) with \(B>\beta +\varrho \). We have \(\lim _{u\rightarrow (\beta +\varrho )/B}=-\infty \) and \(\lim _{u\rightarrow 1}>0\) because \(B-\beta -\varrho >\beta (\beta +\varrho )\) (sufficient condition). Therefore, \(u^{\star }\in ](\beta +\varrho )/B,1[\) is unique.

From the theorem of the implicit function, \(u^{\star }\) is a decreasing function of \(\Psi (\tau )\) and because from (22), we have \(\Psi _{\tau }(\tau )\gtreqqless 0\) when \(\alpha \gtreqqless \varepsilon \), therefore it comes

$$\begin{aligned} u^{\star }={\mathcal {U}}(\tau )\qquad \text{ with } \qquad \mathcal {U}_{\tau }(\tau )\le 0 ~~ \text{ when }~~ \alpha \ge \varepsilon \end{aligned}$$

From (42), we obtain that

$$\begin{aligned} l^{\star }={\mathcal {L}}(\tau )\qquad \text{ with }~~{\mathcal {L}}_{\tau }(\tau )\le 0 ~~ \text{ when }~~ \alpha \ge \varepsilon \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} g^{\star }=B(1-\mathcal {U}(\tau )-{\mathcal {L}}(\tau )) \qquad \text{ with }~~g^{\star }_{\tau }\ge 0 ~~ \text{ when }~~ \alpha \ge \varepsilon \end{aligned}$$

1.2 B.2 The Case \(\beta =0\)

When life expectancy is infinite, \(\beta =0\) and the five Eqs. (1921, 22, 23) becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{x}/x&= \left[ \alpha (1-\tau ) -\Phi (\tau )\right] \Psi (\tau )^{\alpha -1}(z\ u)^{1-\alpha }-\varrho +x\end{aligned}$$
(44)
$$\begin{aligned} \dot{z}/z&= B(1-u-l) - \Phi (\tau )\Psi (\tau )^{\alpha -1}(z\ u)^{1-\alpha }+x\end{aligned}$$
(45)
$$\begin{aligned} \dot{u}/u&= \alpha ^{-1}\left[ B(1-l) -(1-\tau )\alpha \Psi (\tau )^{\alpha -1}(z\ u)^{1-\alpha } \right] -\dot{z}/z \end{aligned}$$
(46)

To obtain the expression of the BGP rate of growth, just remember that \(g^{\star }=r^{\star }-\varrho \) where \(r^{\star }\) is the interest rate along the BGP defined as \(r^{\star }= (1-\tau )\alpha \Psi (\tau )^{\alpha -1}(z^{\star }\ u^{\star })^{1-\alpha }\). Therefore, along the BGP \(\dot{u}=0\), implies that

$$\begin{aligned} r^{\star }=B(1-l^{\star })\qquad \qquad \Rightarrow \qquad \qquad l^{\star }=1-\dfrac{r^{\star }}{B} \end{aligned}$$

Furthermore, from (44),

$$\begin{aligned} x^{\star }=\varrho -\left[ 1-\dfrac{\Phi (\tau )}{\alpha (1-\tau )}\right] \ r^{\star }=\varrho +\Psi (\tau )r^{\star }\end{aligned}$$

and \(\dot{x}-\dot{z}=0\) leads to

$$\begin{aligned} u^{\star }=\dfrac{\varrho }{B} \end{aligned}$$

Therefore Eq. (23) gives the implicit expression of \(r^{\star }\):

$$\begin{aligned} 1-\dfrac{r^{\star }}{B}=\xi _{l}\dfrac{\left[ \varrho +\Psi (\tau )r^{\star }\right] \ \varrho /B}{\left( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) \Psi (\tau )\ r^{\star }} \end{aligned}$$

that is

$$\begin{aligned} B-r^{\star }=\dfrac{\xi _{l}}{\left( \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) \ \Psi (\tau )}\left[ \dfrac{\varrho }{r^{\star }}+\Psi (\tau )\right] \ \varrho \end{aligned}$$

whose the unique solution such that \(r^{\star }-\varrho >0\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} r^{\star }=\dfrac{(1-\alpha )B -\xi _{l}\alpha \varrho +\sqrt{((1-\alpha )B-\xi _{l} \alpha \varrho )^{2}-4\xi _{l} \alpha (1-\alpha )\varrho ^{2}/\Psi (\tau )}}{2(1-\alpha )}>0 \end{aligned}$$

It is straightforward that \(\partial r^{\star }/\partial \Psi (\tau )>0,\,\forall \xi _{l}> 0\). Because \(\partial \Psi (\tau )/\partial \tau \ge 0\) if and only if \(\alpha \ge \varepsilon \) then \(\forall \xi _{l}>0,\,\partial r^{\star }/\partial \tau \ge 0\) if and only if \(\alpha \ge \varepsilon \). When \(\xi _{l}=0,\,r^{\star }=B\) independent from \(\tau \).

Appendix C: Environmental Tax is Applied to Physical Capital Income

From (28), \(\dot{u}=0\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} (z^{\star }\ u^{\star })^{1-\alpha }=\dfrac{\Upsilon (\tau _{k})^{1-\alpha }}{\alpha (1-\tau _{k})}\left[ B(1-l^{\star })-\beta \right] \end{aligned}$$
(47)

with \(\Upsilon (\tau _{k})\equiv 1+\frac{\alpha -\varepsilon }{1-\alpha }\tau _{k}\). Because \(z^{\star }\ u^{\star }>0\), condition (39) \(B>\beta \) always holds.

From (26) and (27), \(\dot{x}-\dot{z}=0\) at the steady-state gives (with 47):

$$\begin{aligned} x^{\star }=\dfrac{\beta (\beta +\varrho )}{B u^{\star }- \beta -\varrho } \end{aligned}$$
(48)

and because condition (41) always holds, \(x^{\star }\ u^{\star }\) is an increasing function of \(u^{\star }\)

Using (23) and (47), we obtain \(l^{\star }=\frac{\xi _{l}\alpha (1-\tau _{k})}{(1-\alpha )\Upsilon (\tau _{k})}\ \times \frac{ x^{\star }\ u^{\star }}{B(1-l^{\star })-\beta } \) which is a quadratic equation of \(l^{\star }\in ]0,1[\) with only one solution verifying \(B(1-u^{\star }-l^{\star })>0\):Footnote 22

$$\begin{aligned} l^{\star }= \dfrac{1}{2}\left( \dfrac{B-\beta -\sqrt{(B-\beta )^{2}-4\frac{ \alpha \xi _{l} (1-\tau _{k})}{(1-\alpha )\Upsilon (\tau _{k})} B\ x^{\star }\ u^{\star }}}{B}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(49)

with \(\partial {l^{\star }}/\partial {u^{\star }}>0\) and \(\partial {l^{\star }}/\partial {\tau _{k}}\le 0\).

\(\dot{z}=0\) leads to, using (27) and (47):

$$\begin{aligned} x^{\star }=Bu^{\star }-\beta + \left( \dfrac{1+(\alpha -\varepsilon )\tau _{k}}{\alpha (1-\tau _{k})}-1\right) \left[ B\left( 1-l^{\star }\right) -\beta \right] \end{aligned}$$
(50)

Equating (48) and (50) enables to express \(u^{\star }\) as the solution of

$$\begin{aligned} Bu^{\star }-\beta + \left( \dfrac{1+(\alpha -\varepsilon )\tau _{k}}{\alpha (1-\tau _{k})}-1\right) \left[ B\left( 1-l^{\star }\right) -\beta \right] -\dfrac{\beta (\beta +\varrho )}{B u- \beta -\varrho }=0 \nonumber \end{aligned}$$

with \(l^{\star }\) defined by Eq. (49). The LHS is increasing in \(u^{\star }\) and \(\tau _{k}\,\forall ~(\alpha ,\varepsilon )\in ]0,1[ \), because \(\partial \left( \frac{1+(\alpha -\varepsilon )\tau _{k}}{\alpha (1-\tau _{k})}-1\right) /\partial \tau _{k}=\frac{1+\alpha -\varepsilon }{\alpha (1-\tau _{k})^{2}}>0\). From (41), \(u^{\star }\in ](\beta +\varrho )/B,1[\) with \(B>\beta +\varrho \). We have \(\lim _{u\rightarrow (\beta +\varrho )/B}=-\infty \) and \(\lim _{u\rightarrow 1}>0\) because \(B-\beta -\varrho >\beta (\beta +\varrho )\) (sufficient condition). Therefore, \(u^{\star }\in ](\beta +\varrho )/B,1[\) is unique.

From the theorem of the implicit function we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} u^{\star }={\mathcal {U}}^{K}(\tau _{k})\quad \text{ with } \quad {\mathcal {U}}^{K}_{\tau _{k}}(\tau _{k})<0 \end{aligned}$$

From (49), we have

$$\begin{aligned} l^{\star }={\mathcal {L}}^{K}(\tau _{k})\qquad \text{ with }~~{\mathcal {L}}^{K}_{\tau _{k}}(\tau _{k})< 0 \end{aligned}$$

and therefore

$$\begin{aligned} g^{\star }=B(1-\mathcal {U}^{K}(\tau _{k})-{\mathcal {L}}^{K}(\tau _{k})) \qquad \text{ with }~~g^{\star }_{\tau _{k}}> 0,~\forall (\alpha ,\varepsilon )\in ]0,1[ \end{aligned}$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pautrel, X. Abatement Technology and the Environment–Growth Nexus with Education. Environ Resource Econ 61, 297–318 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9793-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9793-9

Keywords

Navigation