Skip to main content
Log in

A characterization of two disproportionality and malapportionment indices: the Duncan and Duncan index and the Lijphart index

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Disproportionality indices aim at measuring to what extent the composition of a parliament differs from the distribution of the votes among parties. Malapportionment indices measure to what extent the number of parliament seats attached to each district differs from the distribution of the population among districts. Since there exist many different such indices, some conditions have recently been proposed for assessing the merits of the various indices. In this paper, we propose a characterization of two disproportionality and malapportionment indices: the Duncan and Duncan index (also called Loosemore–Hanby) and the Lijphart index.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In a recent paper, (Nurmi 2014) argues that the concept of proportional representation is both vague and ambiguous. To make things clear, we consider one-option balloting and proportional allocation of seats.

  2. Karpov (2008) and Koppel and Diskin (2009) call this an axiomatic approach.

  3. No disproportionality index has been characterized, yet several characterizations of allocation methods (i.e., techniques to allocate seats to parties in view of the electoral result) are available in the literature (Balinski and Young 1975).

  4. We thus implicitly consider that the size of the set of voters does not matter.

  5. The Duncan and Duncan index is often presented as \(1/2 \times \sum _{i \in N} \left| \pi _{i} - x_{i}/s(x) \right|\). The factor 1/2 is convenient in applications because it scales the index between 0 and 1. We purposefully drop this factor because it makes the index simpler. The difference between the two forms of the index is not more relevant than the difference between a length measurement in meters or in feet.

  6. A characterization of the \(L^{1}\) distance (obviously linked to index \(f_{\text{ DD }}\)) already exists (Fields and Ok 1996). It is not completely relevant to our problem because the authors consider it as a distance between two points in \(\mathbb {R}^{n}\) while we are interested in the ‘distance’ between a point in \(\mathbb {N}^{N}\) and a point in \(\mathbb {Q}^{N}\) with the constraint that the sum of the coordinates be 1.

  7. All proofs are deferred to Sect. 5.

  8. Notice that \(f_{\text{ DD }}\), \(f_{\text{ DD }}^{2}\) and \(\exp (f_{\text{ DD }})\) all induce the same ranking. Actually, all strictly increasing functions of a given index induce the same ranking as that index.

  9. The Rae index is defined as \(f_{\text{ DD }}/n\).

References

  • Aczél, J. (1966). Lectures on functional equations and their applications. Cambridge: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Balinski, M., & Young, H. P. (1975). The quota method of apportionment. The American Mathematical Monthly, 82(7), 701–730.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bell, D. E., Raiffa, H., & Tversky, A. (1988). Decision making: Descriptive, normative, and prescriptive interactions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bolun, I. (2012). Comparison of indices of disproportionality in PR systems. Computer Science Journal of Moldova, 20(2), 246–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D., & Marchant, T. (2007). An axiomatic approach to noncompensatory sorting methods in MCDM, II: More than two categories. European Journal of Operational Research, 178, 246–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bouyssou, D., & Pirlot, M. (2004). Following the traces: An introduction to conjoint measurement without transitivity and additivity. European Journal of Operational Research, 163, 287–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cha, S. H. (2007). Comprehensive survey on distance/similarity measures between probability density functions. International Journal of Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 4(1), 300–307.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duncan, O. D., & Duncan, B. (1955). A methodological analysis of segregation indexes. American Sociological Review, 20(2), 210–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fields, G. S., & Ok, E. A. (1996). The meaning and measurement of income mobility. Journal of Economic Theory, 71(2), 349–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karpov, A. (2008). Measurement of disproportionality in proportional representation. Mathematical and Computer Modelling, 48, 1421–1438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koppel, M., & Diskin, A. (2009). Measuring disproportionality, volatility and malapportionment: axiomatization and solutions. Social Choice and Welfare, 33, 281–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1994). Electoral systems and party systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Loosemore, J., & Hanby, V. (1971). The theoretical limits of maximum distortion: Some analytical expressions for electoral systems. British Journal of Political Science, 1, 467–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luce, R. D., Krantz, D. H., Suppes, P., & Tversky, A. (1990). Foundations of measurement, vol. 3: Representation, axiomatisation and invariance. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagel, S. S. (1984). Public policy: Goals, measurement, and methods. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi, H. (2014). Some remarks on the concept of proportionality. Annals of Operations Research, 215, 231–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rae, D. W. (1967). The political consequences of electoral laws. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera, R., & Grofman, B. (2003). Mapping the indices of seats-votes disproportionality and inter-election volatility. Party Politics, 9, 659–677.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomson, W. (2001). On the axiomatic method and its recent applications to game theory and resource allocation. Social Choice and Welfare, 18, 327–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to T. Marchant.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bouyssou, D., Marchant, T. & Pirlot, M. A characterization of two disproportionality and malapportionment indices: the Duncan and Duncan index and the Lijphart index. Ann Oper Res 284, 147–163 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-3073-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-3073-y

Keywords

Navigation