Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

International environmental outsourcing

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In recent years there has been a dramatic increase in the number of firms shifting stages of their production processes overseas. In this paper we investigate whether firms outsource the dirtier stages of production to minimise domestic environmental regulation costs—a process broadly consistent with the pollution haven hypothesis. We develop a theoretical model of international environmental outsourcing that focuses on the roles played by firm size and productivity, transport costs and environmental regulations. We test the model’s predictions using a firm-level dataset for Japan and do find evidence of an ‘environmental outsourcing’ effect.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A related literature looks directly at the impact of environmental regulations on productivity (see for example Aiken et al. 2009; Greenstone et al. 2011). The PHH is also closely related to the concept of carbon leakage which has encouraged a policy debate on possibility of border trade adjustments to compensate for firms relocating to low environmental regulation countries.

  2. The international trade literature regularly refers to the concept of ‘offshoring’ (e.g. Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg 2008) and several recent papers have attempted to address whether the US is ‘offshoring’, or displacing, its pollution (Kahn 2003; Levinson 2010). It should be noted that offshoring captures all firm activity undertaken abroad. These activities include FDI, joint ventures and arms length trade with affiliates and non-affiliates and hence the offshoring of pollution refers to pollution emanating from all of these activities. International outsourcing however refers only to arms length trade between firms where parts of the production process are undertaken by unrelated firms abroad. Outsourcing is therefore a more precise concept than offshoring. The studies that do look at US offshoring also do so at the level of the industry rather than the firm and as a rule find no evidence that the US has been systematically offshoring pollution.

  3. Although firms may undertake domestic and/or international outsourcing, the focus of this paper is on international outsourcing given the fact that regulatory differences between Japan and many developing economies are likely to be much greater than any regulatory differences within Japan.

  4. Technology differences in production can affect domestic outsourcing similarly although country-level regulations are more likely to result in similar production techniques within a country. Likewise, distances are likely to be lower within a country rather than between countries.

  5. The recent proliferation of trade models based on heterogeneous firms was motivated in part by the empirical studies on firm size, productivity and export behaviour by Tybout and Westbrook (1995), Bernard and Jensen (1995, 1999), Bernard et al. (2003), Aw et al. (2000), Pavcnik (2002) and Eaton et al. (2004).

  6. The level of exports is given by: \( {\text{export}}\,{ = }\,\left( {\sum\nolimits_{s = 1}^{S} {\phi B_{m}^{s} } } \right)\theta_{m} p_{mj}^{1 - \sigma } = \left( {\sum\nolimits_{s = 1}^{S} {\phi B_{m}^{s} } } \right)\theta_{m} \gamma^{1 - \sigma } \left( {(a_{j} + D_{m} )w} \right)^{1 - \sigma } \).

  7. The government sets regulations at z per unit of output a priori. To satisfy z, firms pay abatement costs which when paid reduces z to zero.

  8. Without loss of generality we assume the wage in the foreign country is normalized to unity and intermediate goods are produced under perfect competition and constant return to scale in the foreign country.

  9. To close the model, free entry and exit condition is required as mentioned above. Expected profits in the presence of two types of firms equal entry cost. The free entry and exit condition is re-written as: \( F_{E} = n\int {\pi_{m}^{o} (a_{j} )d\varPhi (a_{j} ) + n\int {\pi_{m} (a_{j} )d\varPhi (a_{j} ).} } \)

  10. In our model \( (\tau_{w} w^{*} + a_{j} w)^{1 - \sigma } > (a_{j} w + D_{m} w)^{1 - \sigma } \) always holds as long as \( O_{m} > A_{m} \) and \( \pi^{o} - \pi = 0 \) holds for a certain a. If \( O_{m} < A_{m} \) then all firms outsource because \( \pi^{o} - \pi^{A} = 0 \). To keep our case interesting we assume that \( O_{m} > A_{m} \).

  11. In more detail: \( \frac{{\partial (\pi^{o} - \pi )}}{{\partial a_{j} }} = \frac{{\gamma^{1 - \sigma } \theta_{m} E}}{{\sigma P^{1 - \sigma } }}(1 - \sigma )w\left\{ {(a_{j} w + \tau_{m} w^{*} )^{ - \sigma } - (a_{j} w + D_{m} w)^{ - \sigma } } \right\} < 0 \) because \( (a_{j} + D_{m} )w > a_{j} w + \tau w^{*} \;{\text{and}}\;\sigma { > 1} \).

  12. Outsourcing is here defined as the contracting out of a part of the production process that was previously handled by the firm itself.

  13. Although our dataset does provide the level of outsourcing undertaken by each firm, our interest is in the decision whether or not to outsource and the factors that influence this decision. We have therefore converted the level of outsourcing into a simple dummy variable equal to 1 if a firm undertakes any outsourcing and 0 otherwise. In a sensitivity analysis we report results based on the level of outsourcing and they are consistent with the main reported results. Unfortunately, our dataset does not provide the country that each firm outsourced to but simply the total value of overseas outsourcing. Note also that our outsourcing variable does not to indicate which part of the production process is outsourced. However, Ito et al. (2007) provide a detailed study of Japanese firm-level outsourcing and show that 52.8 % of outsourcing is to China, 21.9 % to ASEAN countries, 11.58 % to other Asian countries and just 11.47 and 2.24 % to the US/Europe and the rest of the world respectively. From 2002 to 2007 around 72 % of the increase in outsourcing is due to an increase in outsourcing to China.

  14. Although some firm-level abatement cost data are available for Japan, the firms in the sample do not match those in our sample, nor do they provide sufficient industry coverage to provide industry-level observations.

  15. Almost identical rankings are found when we rank our industries in terms of other combinations of the seven questions.

  16. The Japanese industries with the least number of firms answering the environmental questions are also very similar to US and UK industries with the least pollution abatement costs per unit of value added and include industries such as Clothing and Publishing.

  17. We acknowledge that a firm’s transport costs will be a function of both the weight of the product being shipped and the distance that the product has to travel and are likely to relate to the firm’s final product rather than intermediate inputs. Nevertheless, if we assume that the weight of intermediate inputs is correlated with the weight of the final product, and if the final products of firms are shipped similar distances, then transport costs are likely to provide some indication of the potential cost to the firm of importing intermediate inputs.

  18. The first quartile contains the firms with the lowest sales. Replacing sales with the number of workers produces almost identical results.

  19. Table 6 in the appendix indicates, for example, that the mean of the OUTSOURCE dummy is 0.061 implying that 6.1 % of the firms in our sample undertake international outsourcing. Similarly, 26 % of firms answered ‘yes’ to the environmental question 1, 2 or 3, 43 % answered ‘yes’ to the questions 4, 5, 6 or 7 and 57 % answered ‘yes’ to at least one of the questions 1–7.

  20. In terms of calculations, 0.063 = 0.26 * (2.41 * 0.1) where 0.273 is the odds ratio (minus 1) on TRANS and 2.41 is the in sample mean value of TRANS.

  21. These variables are defined in Table 2. We also performed a battery of sensitivity and robustness checks with various combinations of controls which did nothing to alter the general pattern of results. Space prevents us from reporting these results here.

References

  • Aiken, D., Fare, R., Grosskopf, S., & Pasurka, C. A. (2009). Pollution abatement and productivity growth: Evidence from Germany, Japan, the Netherlands, and the United States. Environmental & Resource Economics, 44(1), 11–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti, M., & Wei, S. J. (2005). Fear of service outsourcing: Is it justified? Economic Policy, 20(42), 308–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti, M., & Wei, S. J. (2009). Service offshoring and productivity: Evidence from the US. World Economy, 32(2), 203–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antras, P. (2003). Firms contracts, and trade structure. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1375–1418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antweiler, W., Copeland, B. R., & Taylor, M. S. (2001). Is free trade good for the environment? American Economic Review, 91(4), 877–908.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aw, B. Y., Chung, S., & Roberts, M. (2000). Productivity and turnover in the export market: Micro evidence from Taiwan and South Korea. World Bank Economic Review, 14(1), 65–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, A. B., Eaton, J., Jensen, B., & Kortum, S. (2003). Plants and productivity in international trade. American Economic Review, 93, 1268–1290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, A. B., & Jensen, J. B. (1995). Exporters, jobs, and wages in US manufacturing, 1976–1987. In Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Microeconomics, pp. 67–119.

  • Bernard, A. B., & Jensen, B. (1999). Exceptional exporter performance: Cause, effect, or both? Journal of International Economics, 47(1), 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calia, P., & Ferrante, M. (2013). How do firms combine different internationalisation modes? A multivariate probit approach. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archive, 149(4), 663–696.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, M. A., & Elliott, R. J. R. (2003). Determining the trade-environment composition effect: The role of capital. Labour and Environmental Regulations, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 46(3), 363–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, M. A., & Elliott, R. J. R. (2005). FDI and the capital intensity of ‘dirty’ sectors: A missing piece of the pollution haven puzzle. Review of Development Economics, 9(4), 530–548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, M. A., & Elliott, R. J. R. (2007). Do environmental regulations cost jobs? An industry-level analysis of the UK. B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 7, 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, M. A., Elliott, R. J. R., & Fredriksson, P. (2006). Endogenous pollution havens: Does FDI influence environmental regulations? Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108(1), 157–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, M. A., Elliott, R. J. R., & Shimamoto, K. (2005). Industrial characteristics, environmental regulations and air pollution: An analysis of the UK manufacturing sector. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 50(1), 121–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daveri, F., & Jona-Lasinio, C. (2008). Off-shoring and productivity growth in the Italian manufacturing industries. Economic Studies, 54(3), 414–450.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dijkstra, B. R., Mukherjee, A., & Mathew, A. J. (2011). Environmental regulation: An incentive for foreign direct investment. Review of International Economics, 19(3), 568–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, J., Kortum, S., & Kramarz, F. (2004). Dissecting trade: Firms, industries, and export destinations. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 94(2), 150–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ederington, J., Levinson, A., & Minier, J. (2005). Footloose and pollution-free. Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(1), 92–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger, H., & Egger, P. (2006). International outsourcing and the productivity of low-skilled labor in the EU. Economic Inquiry, 44(1), 98–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott, R. J. R., & Zhou, Y. (2013). Environmental regulation induced foreign direct investment. Environmental & Resource Economics, 55(1), 141–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eskeland, G. S., & Harrison, A. E. (2003). Moving to greener pastures? Multinationals and the pollution haven hypothesis. Journal of Development Economics, 70(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1999). The impact of outsourcing and high technology capital and wages: Estimates for the United States, 199–1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 907–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (2006). Ownership and control in outsourcing to China. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 85–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, R., & Serra, P. (2000). Standards and protection. Journal of International Economics, 52(2), 377–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster-McGregor, N., Stehrer, R., & de Vries, G. J. (2013). Offshoring and the skill structure of labour demand. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archive, 149(4), 631–662.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J. A., & Rose, A. K. (2005). Is trade good or bad for the environment? Sorting out the causality. Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(1), 85–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geishecker, I., & Görg, H. (2013). Services offshoring and wages: Evidence from micro data. Oxford Economic Papers, 65(1), 124–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görg, H., Baumgarten, D., & Geishecker, I. (2013). Offshoring, tasks, and the skill-wage pattern. European Economic Review, 61(1), 132–152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenstone, M., List, J. A., & Syverson, C. (2011). The effects of environmental regulation on the competitiveness of US manufacturing. (Working papers 11-03). Suitland-Silver Hill, MD: Center for Economic Studies, U.S. Census Bureau.

  • Grossman, S., & Hart, O. (1986). The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94(4), 691–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2002). Integration versus outsourcing in industry equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 85–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2005). Outsourcing in a global economy. Review of Economic Studies, 72(1), 135–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G., Helpman, E., & Szeidel, A. (2005). Complementarities between outsourcing and foreign sourcing. American Economic Review, 95, 19–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2008). Trading tasks: A simple theory of offshoring. American Economic Review, 98(5), 1978–1997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., Melitz, M., & Yeaple, S. (2004). Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review, 94(1), 300–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hijzen, A., Inui, T., & Todo, Y. (2010). Does offshoring pay? Firm-level evidence from Japan. Economic Inquiry, 48(4), 880–895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, C. T., & Woo, K. T. (2005). The impact of outsourcing to China on Hong Kong’s labour market. American Economic Review, 95(5), 1673–1687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ito, B., Tomiura, E., & Wakasugi, R. (2007). Dissecting offshore outsourcing and R&D: A survey of Japanese manufacturing firms. (RIETI Discussion Paper Series 05-E-012). Tokyo: Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry.

  • Kahn, M. (2003). The geography of U.S. pollution intensive trade: Evidence from 1959–1994. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 33(4), 383–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leahy, D., & Montagna, C. (2009). Outsourcing vs. FDI in oligopoly equilibrium. Spatial Economic Analysis, 4(2), 149–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levinson, A. (2010). Offshoring pollution: Is the US increasingly importing pollution intensive production? Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 4(1), 63–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lovely, M., & Popp, D. (2011). Trade, technology and the environment: Does access to technology promote environmental regulation? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 61(1), 16–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mattoo, A., Subramanian, A., van der Mensbrugghe, D., & He, J. (2013). Trade effects of alternative carbon border-tax schemes. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 149(3), 587–609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M. J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695–1725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulton, B. (1990). An illustration of a pitfall in estimating the effects of aggregate variables on micro units. Review of Economics and Statistics, 72(2), 334–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pavcnik, N. (2002). Trade liberalization, exit, and productivity improvements: Evidence from Chilean plants. Review of Economics Studies, 69(1), 245–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanna-Randaccio, F., & Sestini, R. (2012). The impact of unilateral climate policy with endogenous plant location and market size asymmetry. Review of International Economics, 20(3), 439–656.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwörer, T. (2013). Offshoring, domestic outsourcing and productivity: Evidence from a number of European countries. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archive, 149(1), 131–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spencer, B. (2005), International outsourcing and incomplete contracts. (NBER Working Paper 11418). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Tomiura, E. (2005). Foreign outsourcing and firm-level characteristics: Evidence from Japanese manufacturers. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 19(2), 255–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tomiura, E. (2007). Foreign outsourcing, exporting, and FDI: A productivity comparison at the firm level. Journal of International Economics, 72(1), 113–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tomiura, E. (2008). Foreign outsourcing and the product cycle: Evidence from micro data. Applied Economics Letters, 15(13), 1019–1022.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tybout, J. R., & Westbrook, M. D. (1995). Trade liberalization and the dimensions of efficiency change in Mexican manufacturing industries. Journal of International Economics, 39(1/2), 53–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wakasugi, R., Ito, B., & Tomiura, E. (2008). Offshoring and trade in East Asia: A statistical analysis. Asian Economic Papers, 7(3), 101–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Access to official micro-data was arranged by the Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and Industry (RIETI). We are grateful for the support of the Daiwa Anglo-Japanese Foundation grant number 7741/7948 and the Leverhulme Trust grant number F/00 094/BH. We thank Toshiyuki Matsuura for assistance with data preparation and Eric Strobl, Toby Kendall, Facundo Albornoz and participants at a RIETI meeting for helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert J. R. Elliott.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 5, 6, 7.

Table 5 Data definitions and sources
Table 6 Summary statistics
Table 7 Correlation matrix

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cole, M.A., Elliott, R.J.R. & Okubo, T. International environmental outsourcing. Rev World Econ 150, 639–664 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-014-0193-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-014-0193-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation