Skip to main content
Log in

Insider trading with different risk attitudes

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the impact of different risk attitudes on the financial decisions of two insiders trading in the stock market. We consider a static version of the Kyle (Econometrica 53:1315–1335, 1985) model with two insiders. Insider 1 is risk neutral while insider 2 is risk averse with negative exponential utility. First, we analytically prove the existence of a unique linear equilibrium. Second, we carry out a comparative static analysis with respect to the duopoly case of risk-neutral insiders (Tighe in Three essays on insider trading. Unpublished Ph.D dissertation, University of Illinois at Champaign-Urbana, 1989) and with respect to the duopoly case of risk-averse insiders (Holden and Subrahmanyam in Econ Lett 44:181–190, 1994) models. Our findings reveal that the market depth and the information revelation are higher in Tighe (1989) than in our model. However, compared to Holden and Subrahmanyam (1994), we find that the market depth depends crucially on the degree of risk aversion. Finally, we show that regardless of the degree of risk aversion, the stock price reveals more information in our model than the stock price in Holden and Subrahmanyam (1994).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For a detailed reference, the reader can check O’Hara (1995) or Vives (2010). Recent extensions considered the one period model of Kyle and risk-neutrality of the insider, include Tighe and Michener (1994), Jain and Mirman (1999), Daher and Mirman (2006), Daher and Mirman (2007), Wang et al. (2009), Zhou (2011), Kyle et al. (2011), Daher et al. (2012), Vitale (2012), Karam and Daher (2013), Daher et al. (2014a), Liu et al. (2017), McLennan et al. (2017), Wang (2017) and Lambert et al. (2018). Other extensions considered the dynamic settings of the Kyle model. Among others, we cite Holden and Subrahmanyam (1992), Caldentey and Stacchetti (2010), Daher et al. (2014b) and Back et al. (2018).

  2. In a recent paper in the industrial organization literature, Mungan (2019) studied the welfare analysis in the presence of two producers, one risk averse and one risk neutral, sharing information regarding the cost of production.

  3. Our paper belongs to a research direction which is interested in proving the existence (or not) and/or uniqueness of Kyle-type model equilibria. See for example, Nöldeke and Tröger (2001, 2006), Caldentey and Stacchetti (2010), Vitale (2012), Daher et al. (2014b), McLennan et al. (2017), Lambert et al. (2018) and Back et al. (2018).

  4. For details, see ECB (2007).

  5. The risk aversion utility function adopted in our model converges to the risk neutral one when the risk aversion coefficient converges to zero (see Marks 2015).

  6. See Tighe (1989) or Holden and Subrahmanyam (1992).

  7. As suggested by one referee, the results of this case will be stated in Lemma 1 and its proof is relegated to “Appendix B”.

  8. Lemma 3 shows that \(\lambda ^*\) is asymptotically convergent to the \(\lambda \) of Kyle (1985).

  9. We invite the reader to check Proposition 3 and Lemma 4 in the “Appendix”.

  10. See for example Tighe (1989), Jain and Mirman (1999), Daher and Mirman (2007), Wang et al. (2009), Daher et al. (2012) and Karam and Daher (2013). In Daher et al. (2014a), the computation of the market depth parameter is quite complex (but not a solution of a quartic equation) due to the real market structure.

  11. See for example Vitale (1995), Holden and Subrahmanyam (1994), Subrahmanyam (1991), Zhang (2004).

  12. See Subrahmanyam (1991), Holden and Subrahmanyam (1994), Vitale (1995) and many related papers.

  13. Subrahmanyam (1991) found the same result with a finite number of partially informed traders and analyzed the impact of the number of the insiders on the market depth parameter.

  14. (Theorem: Descartes’rule of signs) If the terms of a single variable polynomial with real coefficients are ordered by descending variable exponent, then the number of positive roots of the polynomial is either equal to the number of sign differences between consecutive nonzero coefficients, or less than it by a multiple of two.

References

  • Back K, Collin-Dufresne P, Fos V, Li T, Ljungqvist A (2018) Activism, strategic trading, and liquidity. Econometrica 86:1431–1463

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baruch S (2002) Insider trading and risk aversion. J Financ Mark 5(4):451–564

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caldentey R, Stacchetti E (2010) Insider trading with a random deadline. Econometrica 78:245–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chung KH, Chuwonganant C (2014) Uncertainty, market structure, and liquidity. J Financ Econ 113(3):476–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daher W, Mirman LJ (2006) Cournot duopoly and insider trading with two insiders. Q Rev Econ Financ 46:530–551

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daher W, Mirman LJ (2007) Market structure and insider trading. Int Rev Econ Financ 16:306–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daher W, Karam F, Mirman LJ (2012) Insider trading with different market structures. Int Rev Econ Financ 24:143–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daher W, Aydilek H, Karam F, Aydilek A (2014) Insider trading with product differentiation. J Econ 111:173–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daher W, Mirman LJ, Saleeby EG (2014) Two period model of insider trading with correlated signals. J Math Econ 52:57–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank (2007) Measuring financial market liquidity and risk aversion interdependence financial stability review. Section D. European Central Bank, Frankfurt, Germany, pp 176–181

  • Falk A, Enke B, Becker A, Dohmen T, Huffman D, Sunde U (2018) Global evidence on economic preferences. Q J Econ 133(4):1645–1692

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holden C, Subrahmanyam A (1992) Long-lived private information and imperfect competition. J Financ 47:247–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holden C, Subrahmanyam A (1994) Risk-aversion, imperfect competition and long-lived information. Econ Lett 44:181–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jain N, Mirman LJ (1999) Insider trading with correlated signals. Econ Lett 65:105–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karam F, Daher W (2013) Insider trading in a two-tier real market structure model. Q Rev Econ Financ 52:44–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyle A (1985) Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica 53:1315–1335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyle A, Ou-Yang H, Wei B (2011) A model of portfolio delegation and strategic trading. Rev Financ Stud 24(11):3778–3812

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambert NS, Ostrovsky M, Panov M (2018) Strategic trading in informationally complex environments. Econometrica 86(4):1119–1157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu H, Wu J, Yang Q (2017) Inside trading when the market deviates from the semi-strong efficient condition. Ann Econ Financ 18(1):111–128

    Google Scholar 

  • Marks RE (2015) Searching for agents’ best risk profiles. In: Handa H, Ishibuchi M, Ong Y-S, Tan K-C (eds) The proceedings of the 18th Asia Pacific symposium on intelligent and evolutionary systems (IES’2014), chapter 24, volume 1. Proceedings in adaptation, learning and optimization 1:297–309

  • Ma R, Anderson HD, Marshall BR (2019) Risk perceptions and international stock market liquidity. J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 62:92–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLennan A, Monteiro PK, Tourky R (2017) On uniqueness of equilibrium in the Kyle model. Math Financ Econ 11:161–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mungan MC (2019) Sharing of cost related information can increase consumer welfare under risk-aversion. Rev Law Econ 15(2)

  • Nöldeke G, Tröger T (2001) Existence of linear equilibria in the Kyle model with multiple informed traders. Econ Lett 72(2):159–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nöldeke G, Tröger T (2006) A characterization of the distributions that imply existence of linear equilibria in the Kyle model. Ann Financ 2(1):73–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Hara M (1995) Market microstructure theory. Basil Blackwell, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Subrahmanyam A (1991) Risk-aversion, market liquidity and price efficiency. Rev Financ Stud 4:417–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tighe CE (1989) Three essays on insider trading. Unpublished Ph.D dissertation, University of Illinois at Champaign-Urbana

  • Tighe C, Michener R (1994) The political economy of insider trading laws. Am Econ Rev 84:164–168

    Google Scholar 

  • Vayanos D, Wang J (2013) Market liquidity-theory and empirical evidence. In: Constantinides George, Harris Milton, Stulz Rene (eds) Handbook of the economics of finance, chapter 19. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Vitale P (1995) Risk-averse trader with insider information, Discussion paper 9504, Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge

  • Vitale P (2012) Call auction markets with risk-averse specialists. Theor Econ Lett 2:175–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vives X (2010) Information and learning in markets: the impact of market microstructure. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wang LFS, Wang Y-C, Ren S (2009) Stackelberg financial-leader in insider trading model. Int Rev Econ Financ 18:123–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang LFS (2017) Information revelation in an insider trading model with more informed traders. J Adv Econ Financ 2–3:185–194

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang WD (2004) Risk aversion, public disclosure and long-lived information. Econ Lett 85:327–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou WD (2011) Overconfidence on public information. Econ Lett 112:239–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper is dedicated to the memory of Leonard J. Mirman. We are very grateful to the editor Giacomo Corneo and two anonymous referees for offering many insightful comments and suggestions that have improved the article immensely. The authors would like to thank the participants of the Eighth International Conference in Economics July 24–26, 2018, Amsterdam, Netherlands (EconWorld2018) for their helpful comments. All authors contributed equally to this work.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wassim Daher.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendices

1.1 Appendix A: Proof of Proposition 1

We begin by the maximization problem of the risk neutral insider, i.e. insider 1. The decision rule of insider 1 is the function \(x_{1}( {\tilde{z}})\). The expected profits after plugging the linear pricing function, become,

$$\begin{aligned} E[({\tilde{z}}-p(x_{1}({\tilde{z}})+x_{2}({\tilde{z}})+{\tilde{u}}))x_{1}({\tilde{z}} )] = E[({\tilde{z}}-\mu -\lambda (x_{1}({\tilde{z}})+x_{2}({\tilde{z}})+{\tilde{u}} ))x_{1}({\tilde{z}})] \end{aligned}$$

The first and second order conditions are

$$\begin{aligned} x_1({\tilde{z}})= \frac{{\tilde{z}}-\mu -\lambda x_{2}({\tilde{z}})}{2\lambda } \quad {\mathrm {and}} \quad \lambda > 0. \end{aligned}$$
(8)

We move now to solve the maximization of the risk averse insider, i.e. insider 2. The decision rule of insider 2 is the function \(x_{2}( {\tilde{z}}))\). The expected profits after plugging the linear pricing function, become,

$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle E[-e^{-A({\tilde{z}}-p(x_{1}({\tilde{z}})+x_{2}({\tilde{z}})+\tilde{u }))x_{2}({\tilde{z}})}|{\tilde{z}}] = \displaystyle E[-e^{-A({\tilde{z}}-\mu -\lambda (x_{1}({\tilde{z}})+x_{2}({\tilde{z}})+{\tilde{u}}))x_{2}({\tilde{z}})}| {\tilde{z}}] \end{aligned}$$

Using the normality and the independency of the noise traders orders \({\tilde{u}}\), the first and the second order conditions are

$$\begin{aligned} x_2({\tilde{z}})= \frac{{\tilde{z}}-\mu -\lambda x_{1}({\tilde{z}})}{\lambda (2+A\lambda \sigma _{u}^2) } \quad {\mathrm{and}} \quad \lambda (2+A\lambda \sigma _{u}^2)> 0. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

Combining Eqs. 8 and 9, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} x_1({\tilde{z}})= \frac{({\tilde{z}}-\mu )(1+A \lambda \sigma _{u}^2) }{\lambda (3+ 2 A\lambda \sigma _{u}^2) } \quad {\mathrm{and}} \quad x_2({\tilde{z}} )= \frac{({\tilde{z}}-\mu )}{\lambda (3+ 2 A\lambda \sigma _{u}^2) } \end{aligned}$$
(10)

Regarding the price function coefficients, \(\mu \) and \(\lambda \), first note that the semi-strong market efficiency together with linear price function assumption lead to,

$$\begin{aligned} \mu + \lambda {\tilde{r}} = E[{\tilde{z}}|{\tilde{r}}] \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Evaluating the expectation on both sides of Eq. 11 and then applying the law of iterated expectations, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \mu + \lambda {\bar{r}} = {\bar{z}} \end{aligned}$$
(12)

where \({\bar{r}}= {\bar{x}}_1+{\bar{x}}_2+{\bar{u}}= {\bar{x}}_1+{\bar{x}}_2\). Using Eq. 10 to find the expression of \({\bar{r}}\) and plugging the result in Eq. 12, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \mu = {\bar{z}} \end{aligned}$$
(13)

To complete the proof, it remains to find a unique value of the price function slope \(\lambda \). Indeed, note that the linear expressions of the insiders strategies decisions, \({\tilde{x}}_1\) and \({\tilde{x}}_2\), induce the normality distribution of the total order flow \({\tilde{r}}\). Thus, by applying the projection theorem to Eq. 11, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda = \displaystyle \frac{cov({\tilde{z}}, {\tilde{r}})}{var({\tilde{r}})} \end{aligned}$$
(14)

Evaluating the right-hand side of Eq. 14 and after certain arrangement we find that \(\lambda \) is a root of the following quadric equation

$$\begin{aligned} 4A^2\sigma _{u}^4 \mathbf {\lambda ^4} + 12A \sigma _{u}^2 \mathbf {\lambda ^3} +(9- A^2 \sigma _{u}^2 \sigma _{z}^2) \mathbf {\lambda ^2} -3A\sigma _{z}^2 \mathbf {\lambda } -2 \frac{\sigma _{z}^2}{\sigma _{u}^2} = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(15)

By Descartes’ rule of signs,Footnote 14 there is only one positive root satisfying the second order condition which ends the proof. \(\square \)

1.2 Appendix B: Proof of Lemma 1

We first prove the results of Lemma 3 which will be used in many of the subsequent proofs. It should be pointed out that Lemma 3 provides a quantitative characterization for \(\lambda \) as function of A.

Lemma 3

The following statements hold

  1. (i)

    \(\displaystyle \lambda =\frac{1}{2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\) is an asymptote in the \((A,\lambda )\) plane. Moreover, the curve defined by Eq.  5 , will not cross its asymptote.

  2. (ii)

    \(\lambda \)is increasing in A.

Proof of i. To find the asymptote, we view the quartic (Eq. 5)

$$\begin{aligned} f\left( \lambda ,A\right) =4A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}\lambda ^{4}+12A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{3}+\left( 9-A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}\right) \lambda ^{2}-3A\sigma _{z}^{2}\lambda -2\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}=0, \end{aligned}$$
(16)

as a plane algebraic curve.

Note that most of the curves represented by \(f\left( \lambda ,A;\sigma _{z},\sigma _{u}\right) \) are irreducible. We work under this assumption. The projective curve corresponding to the affine curve \(f=0\) is

$$\begin{aligned} F\left( \lambda ,A,Z\right) =4A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}\lambda ^{4}+12A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{3}Z^{2}+\left( 9Z^{4}-A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}Z^{2}\right) \lambda ^{2}-3A\sigma _{z}^{2}\lambda Z^{4}-2\frac{ \sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}Z^{6}=0. \end{aligned}$$
(17)

It is not difficult to see that this projective curve has the singular points \(\left( 0:1:0\right) \) and \(\left( 1:0:0\right) \). Now, we consider the affine view \(Z=1.\) Put \(Z=0\) into the Eq. (17) to get \(A^{2}\lambda ^{4}=0.\) So the points \(\left( 1:0:0\right) \) and \( \left( 0:1:0\right) \) are at infinity. The second of these points is on the A-axis, and as noted above it is singular. Set \(A=1\) in the equation of the projective curve (17), we thus obtain the affine curve

$$\begin{aligned} 4\sigma _{u}^{4}\lambda ^{4}+12\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{3}Z^{2}+\left( 9Z^{4}-\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}Z^{2}\right) \lambda ^{2}-3\sigma _{z}^{2}\lambda Z^{4}-2\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}Z^{6}=0. \end{aligned}$$

The lower order terms \(4\sigma _{u}^{4}\lambda ^{4}-\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}Z^{2}\lambda ^{2}\) give us the distinct tangents \(\lambda =0,\lambda =\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{z}\frac{Z}{\sigma _{u}},\lambda =-\frac{1}{2}\sigma _{z} \frac{Z}{\sigma _{u}}.\) Now dehomogenize to obtain, for \(\lambda >0,\) the affine asymptote \(\lambda =\frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}.\)

Next we show that the curve will not cross its asymptote. The equation of the affine curve above (16) can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 4\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}-\sigma _{z}^{2}\right) \left( \left( \sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda A+3\right) \lambda A+\frac{2}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}\right) =-\lambda ^{2}<0. \end{aligned}$$

This then implies that \(4\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}-\sigma _{z}^{2}<0,\) and so \(\lambda <\frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\) for \(\lambda >0.\)\(\square \)

Proof of ii In this part of the proof, we show that \(\lambda \) is increasing with respect to A where \(\sigma _{u}\) and \( \sigma _{z}\) are treated as parameters. By implicit differentiation, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\lambda }{dA}=-\frac{\frac{\partial f}{\partial A}}{\frac{\partial f}{ \partial \lambda }}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\frac{\partial f}{\partial \lambda }\) must not be zero. It is then simple to find that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\lambda }{dA}=\frac{-8A\sigma _{u}^{4}\lambda ^{4}-12\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{3}+2A\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}\lambda ^{2}+3\sigma _{z}^{2}\lambda }{16A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}\lambda ^{3}+36A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}+2\left( 9-A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}\right) \lambda -3A\sigma _{z}^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

Note that the numerator has one positive root - by Descartes’ rule (since we are interested in \(A\ge 0\)). Now factor the expression, and so we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\lambda }{dA}= & {} \frac{-\lambda \left( 2\sigma _{u}\lambda -\sigma _{z}\right) \left( 2\sigma _{u}\lambda +\sigma _{z}\right) \left( 2\lambda A\sigma _{u}^{2}+3\right) }{ \left( 2\lambda A\sigma _{u}^{2}+3\right) \left( 8A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}+6\lambda -A\sigma _{z}^{2}\right) } \\= & {} -\lambda \left( 2\sigma _{u}\lambda -\sigma _{z}\right) \frac{2\sigma _{u}\lambda +\sigma _{z}}{8A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}+6\lambda -A\sigma _{z}^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

Clearly, \(\frac{d\lambda }{dA}>0\) if \(2\sigma _{u}\lambda -\sigma _{z}<0\), or \(\lambda <\frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\) and provided that \(8A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}+6\lambda -A\sigma _{z}^{2}>0.\)

Consider the upper bound (from part i) to see what is the value of \(f\left( \lambda ,A\right) \) for this value of \(\lambda .\) The evaluation gives that,

$$\begin{aligned} 4A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{4}+12A\sigma _{u}^{2}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{3}+\left( 9-A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}\right) \left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{2}-3A\sigma _{z}^{2}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{ 2\sigma _{u}}\right) -2\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}= \frac{1}{4}\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}>0. \end{aligned}$$

On the other hand, for \(\displaystyle \lambda =\frac{\sqrt{2}\sigma _{z}}{3\sigma _{u}},\) we have

$$\begin{aligned}&4A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}\left( \frac{\sqrt{2}\sigma _{z}}{3\sigma _{u}} \right) ^{4}+12A\sigma _{u}^{2}\left( \frac{\sqrt{2}\sigma _{z}}{3\sigma _{u} }\right) ^{3}+\left( 9-A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}\right) \left( \frac{\sqrt{2}\sigma _{z}}{3\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{2}-3A\sigma _{z}^{2}\left( \frac{\sqrt{2}\sigma _{z}}{3\sigma _{u}}\right) -2\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{ \sigma _{u}^{2}} \\&\quad = -\frac{1}{81}\sigma _{z}^{3}\frac{A}{\sigma _{u}}\left( 2A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}+9\sqrt{2}\right) <0. \end{aligned}$$

This shows that the unique root \(\lambda ^*\) is bracketed between \(\frac{\sqrt{2 }\sigma _{z}}{3\sigma _{u}}\) and \(\frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\) (by the Intermediate Value Theorem).

It remains to show that \(8A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}+6\lambda -A\sigma _{z}^{2}>0.\) Solve

$$\begin{aligned} 8A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}+6\lambda -A\sigma _{z}^{2}=0 \end{aligned}$$

for A, we get \(A=-6\frac{\lambda }{8\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}-\sigma _{z}^{2}}.\) As we are interested in the part of the domain where \(\lambda >0\) and \(A>0,\) then we should have \(8\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}-\sigma _{z}^{2}<0.\) That is \(\lambda ^{2}<\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{8\sigma _{u}^{2}}= \frac{1}{2}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{2}\). But this is lower than the square of the lower bound as \(\left( \frac{\sqrt{2}\sigma _{z} }{3\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{2}-\frac{1}{2}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u} }\right) ^{2}=\)\(\frac{7}{72}\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}.\) Now as \(\lambda >0,\) it is clear that

$$\begin{aligned} 8A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}+6\lambda -A\sigma _{z}^{2}>\left( 8\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}-\sigma _{z}^{2}\right) A. \end{aligned}$$

As the lower bound on \(\lambda ^* \) is \(\frac{\sqrt{2}\sigma _{z}}{3\sigma _{u}} ,\) then \(8\sigma _{u}^{2}\left( \frac{\sqrt{2}\sigma _{z}}{3\sigma _{u}} \right) ^{2}-\sigma _{z}^{2}\)\(=\)\(\frac{7}{9}\sigma _{z}^{2}>0.\) This means \(r\left( \lambda ,A\right) =8A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}+6\lambda -A\sigma _{z}^{2}\) is positive on the domain of interest. \(\square \)

We turn now to prove the results in Lemma 1. Lemma 3 shows that \(\lambda ^*\) is increasing with to respect to A and converges to \(\frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\) as A getting large. Note that \(\frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\) is independent from A and thus it can be treated as constant in our analysis. Hence, one can see that \(x_2({\tilde{z}})= \frac{({\tilde{z}}-\mu )}{\lambda ^*(3+ 2 A\lambda ^*\sigma _{u}^2) }\) converges to zero as A getting large. We show now that the trading order of the risk neutral insider will converge to the one of Kyle (1985) model. Recall the risk neutral insider order in Kyle model and in our model are respectively given by

$$\begin{aligned} x({\tilde{z}})= \frac{({\tilde{z}}-\mu )\sigma _{u}}{ \sigma _{z}} \quad {\mathrm {and}}\quad x_1({\tilde{z}})= \frac{({\tilde{z}}-\mu )(1+A \lambda ^*\sigma _{u}^2) }{\lambda ^*(3+ 2A\lambda ^*\sigma _{u}^2) } \end{aligned}$$

When A is getting large and taking into account that \(\lambda ^*\) is treated as constant (by Lemma 3), one can notice that \(x_1({\tilde{z}})\) converges to \(\frac{({\tilde{z}}-\mu )}{2\lambda ^*}\). Since \(\lambda ^*\) will converge to \(\frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\), replacing its expression in \(x_1({\tilde{z}})\), we obtain the same expression as in Kyle (1985).

1.3 Appendix C: Proof of Lemma 2

Recall that the market depth parameter in Tighe (1989) is given by \( \lambda ^T= \frac{\sqrt{2}}{3}\frac{\sigma _z}{\sigma _u}\) which corresponds to our market depth parameter when A converges to 0. Since we showed in Lemma 3 that \(\lambda ^*\) is increasing in A , the relation in part (a) holds.

We turn now to prove part (b) of Lemma 2. Recall the one-shot game equilibrium of the Holden and Subrahmanyam (1994) model.

Proposition 3

(Holden and Subrahmanyam 1994) In the presence of two risk averse informed traders, a linear equilibrium exists and it is unique. It is characterized by,

(i):
$$\begin{aligned} x_{1}({\tilde{z}})=x_{2}({\tilde{z}})=\displaystyle \frac{({\tilde{z}}-\mu )}{ \lambda ^{HS}(3+A\lambda ^{HS}\sigma _{u}^{2})} \end{aligned}$$
(18)
(ii):

\(p({\tilde{y}})=\mu +\lambda ^{HS}{\tilde{y}},\)where \(\mu ={\bar{z}}\), and \(\lambda ^{HS}\)is the unique strictly positive root of the following quadric equation:

$$\begin{aligned} A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}\mathbf {\lambda ^{4}}+6A\sigma _{u}^{2}\mathbf {\lambda ^{3}}+9\mathbf {\lambda ^{2}}-2A\sigma _{z}^{2}\mathbf {\lambda }-2\frac{ \sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}=0. \end{aligned}$$
(19)

We move now to prove the relation between \(\lambda ^{*}\) and \( \lambda ^{HS}\). Note that (19) can also be considered as an algebraic curve \(g\left( A,\lambda ;\sigma _{u},\sigma _{z}\right) =0,\) where \(\sigma _{u}\) and \(\sigma _{z}\) as viewed as parameters. By implicit differentiation, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\lambda }{dA}=-\frac{\frac{\partial g}{\partial A}}{\frac{\partial g}{ \partial \lambda }}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\frac{\partial g}{\partial \lambda }\) must not be zero. Thus, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\lambda }{dA}=\frac{-\left( 2A\sigma _{u}^{4}\lambda ^{4}+6\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{3}-2\sigma _{z}^{2}\lambda \right) }{4A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}\lambda ^{3}+18A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{2}+18\lambda -2A\sigma _{z}^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

Note that the numerator has one positive root - by Descartes’ rule (since we are interested in \(A\ge 0\)); and we can write this equation as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\lambda }{dA}=\frac{-\lambda \left( \lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}\left( \lambda A\sigma _{u}^{2}+3\right) -\sigma _{z}^{2}\right) }{\lambda \left( \lambda A\sigma _{u}^{2}+3\right) \left( 2\lambda A\sigma _{u}^{2}+3\right) -A\sigma _{z}^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

Observe that \(\frac{d\lambda }{dA}=0,\) implies that

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda \left( \lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}\left( \lambda A\sigma _{u}^{2}+3\right) -\sigma _{z}^{2}\right) =0. \end{aligned}$$

Solving this equation for A,  gives \(A=-\frac{1}{\lambda ^{3}} \frac{3\lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}-\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{4}}.\) Put this expression for A into the quartic to find \(\lambda ,\) we then obtain

\(\lambda =\frac{1}{2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\) or \(\lambda =-\frac{1}{ 2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}.\) Since \(\lambda >0,\) we see that \(g\left( A,\lambda \right) =0,\) for

\(\left( A,\lambda \right) =\left( -\frac{1}{\lambda ^{3}}\frac{3\lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}-\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{4}},\frac{1}{2}\frac{ \sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) =\left( -\frac{1}{\left( \frac{1}{2}\frac{ \sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{3}}\frac{3\left( \frac{1}{2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}-\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{4}},\frac{1}{2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) \) \(=\left( \frac{ 2}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}},\frac{1}{2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) .\)

On the other hand, solve (19) for A to obtain \(A=\frac{1}{ 2\lambda ^{3}\sigma _{u}^{4}}\left( -6\lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}+2\sigma _{z}^{2}\pm 2\sqrt{\left( -4\lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}+\sigma _{z}^{4}\right) }\right) \).

In order to have real roots, we need \(-4\lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}+\sigma _{z}^{4}\ge 0,\) that is \(-4\lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}+\sigma _{z}^{4}\)\(=\)\(-\sigma _{z}^{2}\left( 2\lambda \sigma _{u}-\sigma _{z}\right) \left( 2\lambda \sigma _{u}+\sigma _{z}\right) \ge 0,\) or equivalently, \(\left( 2\lambda \sigma _{u}-\sigma _{z}\right) \left( 2\lambda \sigma _{u}+\sigma _{z}\right) \le 0.\) This means that \(\left( 2\lambda \sigma _{u}-\sigma _{z}\right) \le 0\), that is \(\lambda \le \frac{1}{2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{ \sigma _{u}}.\)

So this bound is the maximal value of \(\lambda .\) By the analysis above, this happens when \(A=\frac{2}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}.\) We now study the sign of \(\frac{d\lambda }{dA}.\) If we evaluate \(\frac{d\lambda }{dA}\) at \(A=0\), we get

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\lambda }{dA}|_{A=0}=\frac{-\left( 6\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{3}-2\sigma _{z}^{2}\lambda \right) }{18\lambda }=-\frac{1}{3}\lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}+\frac{1}{9}\sigma _{z}^{2}. \end{aligned}$$

Now when \(A=0\) , \(g\left( 0,\lambda \right) =9\lambda ^{2}-2\frac{ \sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}=0\), which has the solutions \(\lambda =\pm \frac{1}{3}\sqrt{2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}.\) Since \(\lambda >0,\) we get that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\lambda }{dA}|_{A=0}=\frac{-\left( 6\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{3}-2\sigma _{z}^{2}\lambda \right) }{18\lambda }=-\frac{1}{3}\left( \frac{1 }{3}\sqrt{2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}+\frac{ 1}{9}\sigma _{z}^{2}=\frac{1}{27}\sigma _{z}^{2}>0. \end{aligned}$$

On the other hand, one can show that \(\frac{d\lambda }{dA}|_{A= \frac{3}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}}<0\). Thus, the derivative at \(A=0\) is positive, and to the right of A at \(A=\frac{3}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}\) is negative. This shows that the plane curve described by \(g\left( A,\lambda \right) =0,\) has a max given by \(\left( A,\lambda \right) =\left( \frac{2}{ \sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}},\frac{1}{2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) .\) So we can conclude that the algebraic curve \(g=0\) is unimodal. In fact, this can be verified by computing the second derivative of lambda with respect to A, which evaluates at \(\left( \frac{2}{\sigma _{u}\sigma _{z}},\frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right) \), is equal to \(-\frac{1}{128} (\sigma _z)^3 (\sigma _u)<0.\) This shows that it is concave down on the region containing the maximum point.

Now, computing the first derivative of \(\lambda ^*\) with respect to A when \(A=0\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\lambda ^* }{dA}|_{A=0}= & {} -\frac{1}{6}\left( 2\lambda \sigma _{u}-\sigma _{z}\right) \left( 2\lambda \sigma _{u}+\sigma _{z}\right) \\= & {} -\frac{1}{6}\left( 2\left( \frac{1}{3}\sqrt{2}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) \sigma _{u}-\sigma _{z}\right) \left( 2\left( \frac{1}{3}\sqrt{2 }\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) \sigma _{u}+\sigma _{z}\right) \\= & {} -\frac{1}{54}\sigma _{z}^{2}\left( 2\sqrt{2}-3\right) \left( 2\sqrt{2} +3\right) =\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{54}>0 \end{aligned}$$

This shows that the initial slope in Holden and Subrahmanyam (1994) case is exactly twice that of obtained in our case. Consider now the difference \(h=g-f\), we get

$$\begin{aligned} h\left( A,\lambda \right) =\lambda A\left( -3A\lambda ^{3}\sigma _{u}^{4}-6\lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}+\sigma _{z}^{2}+A\lambda \sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}\right) \end{aligned}$$

So to find the intersection of f and gh must vanish. Then either \(\lambda A=0\) or \(-3A\lambda ^{3}\sigma _{u}^{4}-6\lambda ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}+\sigma _{z}^{2}+A\lambda \sigma _{u}^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}=0.\) The cubic polynomial has one sign change, and therefore, it has one positive root by Descarte’s sign rule.

We show in the table below that at \(A=\frac{3}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}},\)\(f<g,\) but that at \(A=\frac{4}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}},\)\(f>g.\) It also shows the intersection point .

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{llll} \lambda \backslash A &{} \frac{3}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}} &{} \frac{4}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}} &{} \frac{3.5}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}} \\ \lambda {\text { from }}f=0 &{} .\, 492\,91\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}} &{} .\, 494\,81\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}} &{} .\, 493\,97\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}} \\ \lambda {\text { from }}g=0 &{} .\, 497\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}} &{} .\, 490\,51\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}} &{} .\, 494\,02\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}} \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

Note that the intersection point is roughly \(\left( {\tilde{A}},{\tilde{\lambda }} \right) =\left( \frac{3.5}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}} ,.\, 494\,\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) \).

Summarizing, we have that

  1. 1.

    the initial slope of g is bigger than the initial slope of f

  2. 2.

    g is unimodal, it has one critical point which is a maximum occuring at \(A=\frac{2}{\sigma _{u}\sigma _{z}};\)

  3. 3.

    the intersection point of f and g occurs to the right of the maximum of g,  at roughly \(A^{*}\simeq \frac{3.5}{\sigma _{u}\sigma _{z}};\)

  4. 4.

    \(h=0\) at two points.

Then it follows that there is one point \(\left( {\tilde{A}},{\tilde{\lambda }} \right) ,\) where \(\lambda <\lambda _{HS}\) for \(A<{\tilde{A}},\) and \( \lambda >\lambda _{HS}\) for \(A>{\tilde{A}}.\)\(\square \)

1.4 Appendix D: Proof of Proposition 2

Recall that the conditional variance in Tighe (1989) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} var ({\tilde{z}}|{\tilde{y}}) = \frac{1}{3} \sigma _{z}^2 \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Computing the conditional variances in our model and in the Holden and Subrahmanyam (1994) model, we obtain respectively

$$\begin{aligned} var({\tilde{z}}|{\tilde{y}})= & {} \frac{\left( 3\left( 1+A\lambda ^* \sigma _{u}^{2}\right) ^{2}+2\left( 1+A\lambda ^* \sigma _{u}^{2}\right) \right) \sigma _{z}^{2}-(\lambda ^*)^{2}\left( 2\left( 1+A\lambda ^* \sigma _{u}^{2}\right) +1\right) ^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}}{ \left( 2\left( 1+A\lambda ^* \sigma _{u}^{2}\right) +1\right) ^{2}}, \end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned} var({\tilde{z}}|{\tilde{y}})= & {} \frac{[(3+A\lambda ^{HS} \sigma _{u}^{2})^{2}-4]\sigma _{z}^{2}-(\lambda ^{HS})^{2}(3+A\lambda ^{HS} \sigma _{u}^{2})^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}}{(3+A\lambda ^{HS} \sigma _{u}^{2})^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

We begin first by showing that (20) is less than (21). Indeed, combining (21) with (15) and after some simplifications, the problem becomes equivalent to show that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{3}<\frac{ 3+5A\lambda ^* \sigma _{u}^{2}+2(\lambda ^*) ^{2}A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}}{\left( 2\left( 1+A\lambda ^* \sigma _{u}^{2}\right) +1\right) ^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Plugging the lower bound, \(\lambda ^T\), (the upper bound, \(\frac{\sigma _z}{2\sigma _u}\)) of \(\lambda ^*\) found in Lemma in the numerator (denominator) of the right hand side of (23), we obtain,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ 3+5A\sigma _{u}^{2}\left( \frac{\sqrt{2}}{3}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{\sigma _{u}}\right) +2\left( \frac{\sqrt{2}}{3}\frac{\sigma _{z}}{ \sigma _{u}}\right) ^{2}A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}}{\left( 2\left( 1+A\left( \frac{ \sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right) \sigma _{u}^{2}\right) +1\right) ^{2}}< \frac{ 3+5A\lambda \sigma _{u}^{2}+2\lambda ^{2}A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}}{\left( 2\left( 1+A\lambda \sigma _{u}^{2}\right) +1\right) ^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

The left hand side simplifies to

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{3}+\frac{\left( \left( 15\sqrt{2}-18\right) A\sigma _{u}\sigma _{z}+\sigma _{z}^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}A^{2}\right) }{9\left( 3+A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}\right) ^{2}}>\frac{1}{3}. \end{aligned}$$

This completes the first part of the proof. It remains to show that the conditional variance in our model is less than the conditional variance in Holden and Subrahmanyam model (1994). Indeed, combining (21) with (15) and combining (22) with (19), the problem reduces to showing that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1+A\lambda ^{*}\sigma _{u}^{2}}{3+2A\lambda ^{*}\sigma _{u}^{2} }\le \frac{A\lambda ^{HS}\sigma _{u}^{2}+1}{A\lambda ^{HS}\sigma _{u}^{2}+3} . \end{aligned}$$
(24)

In order to complete the proof, we need to show first the following result.

Lemma 4

\(\lambda ^{HS}\in \left[ \frac{\sigma _{z}}{4\sigma _{u}},\frac{ \sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right] \).

Proof

Consider the equation

$$\begin{aligned} g(\lambda )=A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}\lambda ^{4}+6A\sigma _{u}^{2}\lambda ^{3}+9\lambda ^{2}-2A\sigma _{z}^{2}\lambda -2\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}, \end{aligned}$$
(25)

such that \(g(\lambda ^{HS})=0\). Note that

$$\begin{aligned} g\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{4\sigma _{u}}\right)= & {} A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{4\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{4}+6A\sigma _{u}^{2}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{4\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{3}+9\left( \frac{ \sigma _{z}}{4\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{2}-2A\sigma _{z}^{2}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{4\sigma _{u}}\right) -2\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}} \\= & {} \frac{1}{256}A^{2}\sigma _{z}^{4}-\frac{13}{32}\frac{A}{ \sigma _{u}}\sigma _{z}^{3}-\frac{23}{16}\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}= \frac{1}{256}\sigma _{z}^{2}\frac{A^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}-104A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}-368}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

Consider the numerator \(A^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}-104A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}-368=0\). It has the solutions \(A=4\frac{ 13+8\sqrt{3}}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}=\frac{107.\, 43}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}\) or \(\ A=4\frac{13-8\sqrt{3}}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}=\)\(- \frac{3.\, 425\,6}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}.\) Now, the derivative

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\left( \frac{1}{256}\sigma _{z}^{2}\frac{A^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}-104A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}-368}{\sigma _{u}^{2}} \right) }{dA}= \frac{1}{128}\frac{\sigma _{z}^{3}}{\sigma _{u}} \left( A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}-52\right) . \end{aligned}$$

So for \(0\le A<\frac{52}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}\), the derivative is negative and \(g\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{4\sigma _{u}}\right) \) (at this value only) is decreasing in A for \(0\le A<\frac{52}{\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}\). As also for \(A=0,\)\(g\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{4\sigma _{u}}\right) =9\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{4\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{2}-2\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2} }{\sigma _{u}^{2}}\)\(=-\frac{23}{16}\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}\) is negative, we can conclude that \(\frac{\sigma _{z}}{4\sigma _{u}}\) is a lower bound for \(\lambda \). Similarly, it follows from what we had before,

$$\begin{aligned}&A^{2}\sigma _{u}^{4}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{4}+6A\sigma _{u}^{2}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{3}+9\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right) ^{2}-2A\sigma _{z}^{2}\left( \frac{\sigma _{z}}{2\sigma _{u}}\right) -2\frac{\sigma _{z}^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}} \\&\quad = \frac{1}{16}\sigma _{z}^{2}\frac{A^{2}\sigma _{z}^{2}\sigma _{u}^{2}-4A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}+4}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}= \frac{1}{16 }\sigma _{z}^{2}\frac{\left( A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}-2\right) ^{2}}{\sigma _{u}^{2}}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, by the Intermediate Value Theorem, the proof of Lemma 3 is complete. \(\square \)

We turn now to show that (24) holds. Since the expressions in (24) are both monotonically increasing in \(\lambda \), plugging the lower bound of Lemma 4 in the right hand side of (24), and plugging the upper bound of Lemma 4 in the left hand side of (24), and then subtracting the resulting expressions from each others, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{2}\frac{2+A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}{3+A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}}-\frac{ A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}+4}{A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}+12}=-\frac{1}{2}\frac{ \left( A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}\right) ^{2}}{\left( 3+A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}\right) \left( A\sigma _{z}\sigma _{u}+12\right) }<0. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

This completes the proof of Proposition 2. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Daher, W., Aydilek, H. & Saleeby, E.G. Insider trading with different risk attitudes. J Econ 131, 123–147 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-020-00703-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-020-00703-x

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation