Abstract
We investigate a type of public goods games played in groups of individuals who choose how much to contribute towards the production of a common good, at a cost to themselves. In these games, the common good is produced based on the sum of contributions from all group members, then equally distributed among them. In applications, the dependence of the common good on the total contribution is often nonlinear (e.g., exhibiting synergy or diminishing returns). To date, most theoretical and experimental studies have addressed scenarios in which the set of possible contributions is discrete. However, in many real-world situations, contributions are continuous (e.g., individuals volunteering their time). The “n-player snowdrift games” that we analyze involve continuously varying contributions. We establish under what conditions populations of contributing (or “cooperating”) individuals can evolve and persist. Previous work on snowdrift games, using adaptive dynamics, has found that what we term an “equally cooperative” strategy is locally convergently and evolutionarily stable. Using static evolutionary game theory, we find conditions under which this strategy is actually globally evolutionarily stable. All these results refer to stability to invasion by a single mutant. We broaden the scope of existing stability results by showing that the equally cooperative strategy is locally stable to potentially large population perturbations, i.e., allowing for the possibility that mutants make up a non-negligible proportion of the population (due, for example, to genetic drift, environmental variability or dispersal).



Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
Condition (14) compares the incremental benefit of contributing \(H^*\) to its cost.
References
Archetti M (2013) Evolutionary game theory of growth factor production: implications for tumour heterogeneity and resistance to therapies. Br J Cancer 109(4):1056–1062
Archetti M (2014) Evolutionary dynamics of the Warburg effect: glycolysis as a collective action problem among cancer cells. J Theor Biol 341:1–8
Archetti M, Ferraro DA, Christofori G (2015) Heterogeneity for IGF-II production maintained by public goods dynamics in neuroendocrine pancreatic cancer. Proc Natl Acad Sci 112(6):1833–1838
Archetti M, Scheuring I (2011) Coexistence of cooperation and defection in public goods games. Evolution 65(4):1140–1148
Archetti M, Scheuring I (2012) Review: game theory of public goods in one-shot social dilemmas without assortment. J Theor Biol 299:9–20
Bach LA, Bentzen S, Alsner J, Christiansen FB (2001) An evolutionary-game model of tumour-cell interactions: possible relevance to gene therapy. Euro J Cancer 37(16):2116–2120
Barker JL, Barclay P, Reeve HK (2012) Within-group competition reduces cooperation and payoffs in human groups. Behav Ecol 23(4):735–741
Box GE (1976) Science and statistics. J Am Stat Assoc 71(356):791–799
Boyd R, Richerson PJ (2002) Group beneficial norms can spread rapidly in a structured population. J Theor Biol 215(3):287–296
Brännström Å, Gross T, Blasius B, Dieckmann U (2010) Consequences of fluctuating group size for the evolution of cooperation. J Math Biol 63(2):263–281. Available from doi: 10.1007/s00285-010-0367-3
Brown JS, Vincent TL (2008) Evolution of cooperation with shared costs and benefits. Proc R Soc B 275(1646):1985–1994. Available from doi:10.1098/rspb.2007.1685
Brown S (1999) Cooperation and conflict in host-manipulating parasites. Proc R Soc Lond B Biol Sci 266(1431):1899–1904
Brown SP, Hochberg ME, Grenfell BT (2002) Does multiple infection select for raised virulence? Trends Microbiol 10(9):401–405
Browning M, Chiappori PA, Weiss Y (2014) Economics of the family. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Buma B, Wessman C (2011) Disturbance interactions can impact resilience mechanisms of forests. Ecosphere 2(5):art64
Chen X, Szolnoki A, Perc M, Wang L 2012 Impact of generalized benefit functions on the evolution of cooperation in spatial public goods games with continuous strategies. Phys Rev E 85(6). Available from doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.85.066133
Christiansen FB (1991) On conditions for evolutionary stability for a continuously varying character. Am Nat 138(1):37–50
Clutton-Brock T (2002) Breeding together: kin selection and mutualism in cooperative vertebrates. Science 296(5565):69–72
Clutton-Brock T (2009) Cooperation between non-kin in animal societies. Nature 462(7269):51–57
Cordero OX, Ventouras LA, DeLong EF, Polz MF (2012) Public good dynamics drive evolution of iron acquisition strategies in natural bacterioplankton populations. Proc Natl Acad Sci 109(49):20059–20064
Cornforth DM, Sumpter DJ, Brown SP, Brännström Å (2012) Synergy and group size in microbial cooperation. Am Nat 180(3):296
Dale VH, Joyce LA, McNulty S, Neilson RP, Ayres MP, Flannigan MD et al (2001) Climate change and forest disturbances: climate change can affect forests by altering the frequency, intensity, duration, and timing of fire, drought, introduced species, insect and pathogen outbreaks, hurricanes, windstorms, ice storms, or landslides. BioScience 51(9):723–734
Deng K, Chu T (2011) Adaptive evolution of cooperation through Darwinian dynamics in public goods games. PLoS One 6(10):e25496. Available from doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0025496
Dieckmann U, Law R (1996) The dynamical theory of coevolution: a derivation from stochastic ecological processes. J Math Biol 34(5–6):579–612
Doebeli M, Hauert C, Killingback T (2004) The evolutionary origin of cooperators and defectors. Science 306(5697):859–862
Dugatkin LA (1997) Cooperation among animals: an evolutionary perspective: an evolutionary perspective. Oxford University Press, USA
Fehr E, Gächter S (1999) Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. Institute for empirical research in economics working paper (10)
Fehr E, Gächter S (2002) Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415(6868):137–140
Frank SA (2010) A general model of the public goods dilemma. J Evol Biol 23(6):1245–1250
Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1991) Game Theory. MIT Press, Cambridge
Fujita H, Aoki S, Kawaguchi M (2014) Evolutionary dynamics of nitrogen fixation in the Legume-Rhizobia symbiosis. PLoS One 9(4):e93670. Available from doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0093670
Gardner A, West S (2006) Demography, altruism, and the benefits of budding. J Evol Biol. 19(5):1707–1716
Gavrilets S (2015) Collective action problem in heterogeneous groups. Philos Trans R Soc B 370(1683):20150016
Geritz SA, Mesze G, Metz JA et al (1998) Evolutionarily singular strategies and the adaptive growth and branching of the evolutionary tree. Evol Ecol 12(1):35–57
Gokhale CS, Traulsen A (2014) Evolutionary multiplayer games. Dyn Games Appl 4(4):468–488. Available from doi:10.1007/s13235-014-0106-2
Hardin G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science 162(3859):1243–1248
Hartl DL, Clark AG (2007) Principles of population genetics. Sinauer Associates, Sunderland
Hauert C (2006) Cooperation, collectives formation and specialization. Adv Complex Syst 9(04):315–335
Hauert C (2008) Evolution from cellular to social scales. In: Skjeltorp AT, Belushkin AV (eds) Evolutionary dynamics. Springer, Berlin, pp 11–44
Hauert C, Doebeli M (2004) Spatial structure often inhibits the evolution of cooperation in the snowdrift game. Nature 428(6983):643–646
Hauert C, Holmes M, Doebeli M (2006) Evolutionary games and population dynamics: maintenance of cooperation in public goods games. Proc R Soc B 273(1600):2565–2571. Available from doi: 10.1098/rspb.2006.3600
Hauert C, Michor F, Nowak MA, Doebeli M (2006) Synergy and discounting of cooperation in social dilemmas. J Theor Biol 239(2):195–202
Hauert C, De Monte S, Hofbauer J, Sigmund K (2002) Replicator dynamics for optional public good games. J Theor Biol 218(2):187–194
Hirsch MW, Smale S, Devaney RL (2013) Differential equations, dynamical systems, and an introduction to chaos, 3rd edn. Academic Press, Waltham
Hofbauer J, Sigmund K (1998) Evolutionary games and population dynamics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Houston AI, Davies NB (1985) The evolution of cooperation and life history in the Dunnock, Prunella modularis. In: Sibly RM, Smith RH (eds) Behavioural ecology: ecological consequences of adaptive behaviour. Blackwell Scientific Publications, Oxford, pp 471–487
Ito K, Ohtsuki H, Yamauchi A (2015) Relationship between aggregation of rewards and the possibility of polymorphism in continuous snowdrift games. J Theor Biol 372:47–53. Available from doi:10.1016/j.jtbi.2015.02.015
Kagel JH, Roth AE (1995) The handbook of experimental economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Killingback T, Doebeli M (2002) The continuous prisoners dilemma and the evolution of cooperation through reciprocal altruism with variable investment. Am Nat 160(4):421–438
Killingback T, Doebeli M, Hauert C (2010) Diversity of cooperation in the tragedy of the commons. Biol Theory 5:3–6
Kraak S (2011) Exploring the public goods game model to overcome the tragedy of the commons in fisheries management. Fish Fish 12(1):18–33
Krupp DB, Debruine LM, Barclay P (2008) A cue of kinship promotes cooperation for the public good. Evol Human Behav 29(1):49–55
Krupp D, Taylor PD (2015) Social evolution in the shadow of asymmetrical relatedness. Proc R Soc Lond B Biol Sci 282(1807):20150142
Kümmerli R, Gardner A, West SA, Griffin AS (2009) Limited dispersal, budding dispersal, and cooperation: an experimental study. Evolution 63(4):939–949
Leighton GM (2014) Sex and individual differences in cooperative nest construction of sociable weavers Philetairus socius. J Ornithol 155(4):927–935
Liang H, Cao M, Wang X (2015) Analysis and shifting of stochastically stable equilibria for evolutionary snowdrift games. Syst Control Lett 85:16–22. Available from doi:10.1016/j.sysconle.2015.08.004
Lotem A, Fishman MA, Stone L (1999) Evolution of cooperation between individuals. Nature 400(6741):226–227
Markman S, Yom-Tov Y, Wright J (1995) Male parental care in the orange-tufted sunbird: behavioural adjustments in provisioning and nest guarding effort. Anim Behav 50(3):655–669
Maynard Smith J (1982) Evolution and the theory of games. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Maynard Smith J, Price G (1973) lhe logic of animal conflict. Nature 246:15
McGill BJ, Brown JS (2007) Evolutionary game theory and adaptive dynamics of continuous traits. Ann Rev Ecol Syst 38(1):403–435. Available from doi:10.1146/annurev.ecolsys.36.091704.175517
McNamara JM, Barta Z, Fromhage L, Houston AI (2008) The coevolution of choosiness and cooperation. Nature 451(7175):189–192. Available from doi:10.1038/nature06455
McNamara JM, Gasson CE, Houston AI (1999) Incorporating rules for responding into evolutionary games. Nature 401(6751):368–371
Metz JA, Geritz SA, Meszéna G, Jacobs FJ, Van Heerwaarden JS et al (1996) Adaptive dynamics, a geometrical study of the consequences of nearly faithful reproduction. Stoch Spat Struct Dyn Syst 45:183–231
Milinski M, Semmann D, Krambeck HJ (2002) Reputation helps solve the tragedy of the commons. Nature 415(6870):424–426
Motro U (1991) Co-operation and defection: playing the field and the ESS. J Theor Biol 151(2):145–154
Motro U, Cohen D (1989) A note on vigilance behavior and stability against recognizable social parasites. J Theor Biol 136(1):21–25
Nowak MA (2006) Evolutionary dynamics: exploring the equations of life. Harvard University Press, Massachusetts
Nowak MA, Sigmund K (1998) Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature 393(6685):573–577
Nowak MA, Sigmund K (2004) Evolutionary dynamics of biological games. Science 303(5659):793–799
Parker GA, Royle NJ, Hartley IR (2002) Intrafamilial conflict and parental investment: a synthesis. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B Biol Sci 357(1419):295–307
Pfeiffer T, Bonhoeffer S (2003) An evolutionary scenario for the transition to undifferentiated multicellularity. Proc Natl Acad Sci 100(3):1095–1098
Poulin R (1994) The evolution of parasite manipulation of host behaviour: a theoretical analysis. Parasitology 109(S1):S109–S118
Pulliam HR, Pyke GH, Caraco T (1982) The scanning behavior of juncos: a game-theoretical approach. J Theor Biol 95(1):89–103
Rainey PB, Rainey K (2003) Evolution of cooperation and conflict in experimental bacterial populations. Nature 425(6953):72–74
Reeve HK, Hölldobler B (2007) The emergence of a superorganism through intergroup competition. Proc Natl Acad Sci 104(23):9736–9740
Ross SM (2010) A First Course in Probability. Pearson Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River
Santos FC, Santos MD, Pacheco JM (2008) Social diversity promotes the emergence of cooperation in public goods games. Nature 454(7201):213–216. Available from doi:10.1038/nature06940
Sasaki T, Okada I (2015) Cheating is evolutionarily assimilated with cooperation in the continuous snowdrift game. Biosystems 131:51–59. Available from doi:10.1016/j.biosystems.2015.04.002
Savage JL, Russell AF, Johnstone RA (2015) Maternal allocation in cooperative breeders: should mothers match or compensate for expected helper contributions? Anim Behav 102:189–197
Souza MO, Pacheco JM, Santos FC (2009) Evolution of cooperation under N-person snowdrift games. J Theor Biol 260(4):581–588
Taylor PD (1989) Evolutionary stability in one-parameter models under weak selection. Theor Popul Biol 36(2):125–143
Trivers RL (1971) The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Q Rev Biol 246(1):35–57
Wright J, Cuthill I (1990) Biparental care: short-term manipulation of partner contribution and brood size in the starling, Sturnus vulgaris. Behav Ecol 1(2):116–124
Wu T, Fu F, Wang L (2009) Partner selections in public goods games with constant group size. Phys Rev E 80(2). Available from doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.80.026121
Acknowledgments
We are grateful to Sigal Balshine, Pat Barclay, Ben Bolker, Jonathan Dushoff, Paul Higgs, Rufus Johnstone and Danny Krupp for valuable discussions and comments.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Funding
We were supported by NSERC (DE), the Ontario Trillium Foundation (CM) and the department of Mathematics and Statistics at McMaster University (CM).
Conflict of interest
The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.
Appendices
Appendix 1: Motivation for assumption A3 (existence of \(\eta _\mathrm{max}\))
In this appendix, we motivate assumption A3 by showing that if the focal agent’s fitness is defined by Eq. (5) and f is continuous, the following two statements are equivalent:
- S1 :
-
For any fixed non-focal agent’s mean contribution H there exists \(h^\dag (H)\ge 0\) such that the focal agent’s fitness W(h, H) decreases with its contribution h for all \(h>h^\dag (H)\).
- S2 :
-
There exists \(\eta _\mathrm{max}\ge 0\) such that \(f(\eta ) - \eta \) decreases with \(\eta \) for all \(\eta >\eta _\mathrm{max}\).
To gain some intuition, we first suppose f is a differentiable function of \(\eta \) (in Appendix 1.1), and then give the general proof (in Appendix 1.2)
1.1 Appendix 1.1: Proof for differentiable f
Suppose that f is differentiable. Then, by the chain rule and Eq. (3), S1 implies that
Consequently, if W(h, H) decreases with h for \(h>h^\dag (H)\) then \(f(\eta ) - \eta \) decreases with \(\eta \) for all \(\eta >\eta (h^\dag (H),H)\). Letting
\(f(\eta ) - \eta \) decreases for \(\eta >\eta _\mathrm{max}\). Thus, S1 implies S2.
Conversely, if there exists \(\eta _\mathrm{max}\ge 0\) such that \(f(\eta ) - \eta \) decreases for \(\eta >\eta _\mathrm{max}\), then letting \(h^\dag (H) = \eta _\mathrm{max}- (n-1)H\), we see that \(\eta (h,H)>\eta _\mathrm{max}\) iff \(h>h^\dag (H)\). It then follows from Eq. (51) that W(h, H) decreases with h for \(h>h^\dag (H)\), so S2 implies S1.
1.2 Appendix 1.2: Proof for general f
Suppose S1 holds. Noting that
where
and rewriting Eq. (5) as
we see that S1 is equivalent to the assumption that for fixed H there exists \(\eta ^\dag (H)\ge 0\) such that \(f(\eta ) -\eta \) decreases for \(\eta >\eta ^\dag (H)\). We define \(\eta _\mathrm{max}\) to be the minimal such (non-negative) total good. Because \(\eta \) can vary independently of H, it follows that \(f(\eta )-\eta \) decreases for all \(\eta >\eta _\mathrm{max}\), so S1 implies S2.
Conversely, if S2 is true, then Eqs. (53) and (55) imply that W(h, H) decreases for all \(h>h^\dag (H) = \eta _\mathrm{max}- (n-1)H\). Thus, S2 implies S1.
Appendix 2: Boundary ESSs need not be singular strategies
In adaptive dynamics, evolutionarily singular points are singled out as candidate ESSs (e.g., Geritz et al. 1998; Doebeli et al. 2004). These are points at which there is no directional selection, since the fitness gradient D(H) vanishes.
However, when the evolving variable H is restricted to an interval (in our case \(H\ge 0\)), it is not necessary for the fitness gradient to vanish at an endpoint of this interval in order for it to be ES: as we have seen in Theorem 4.1, for the class of models defined in Sect. 2, the endpoint \(H=0\) is globally evolutionarily stable whenever \(f(\eta _\mathrm{max})<\eta _\mathrm{max}\), but the fitness gradient is negative in a right-hand neighbourhood of the endpoint \(H=0\) (including at \(H=0\)). In fact, it is D(H) being negative near \(H=0\) that ensures that \(H=0\) is both locally convergently and evolutionarily stable.
The source of this issue is that the restriction to the biologically meaningful interval \(H\ge 0\) is not built into the dynamical model Eq. (12), in that solutions of Eq. (12) do not necessarily remain in this interval (because the fitness gradient at the left endpoint \(H=0\) points outside the interval, into \(H<0\)).
Note also that this cannot be easily fixed by artificially setting \(D(0) = 0\), because doing so will insert a discontinuity into the fitness gradient, and adaptive dynamics assumes that the fitness gradient is at least continuous, in order to ensure the existence of solutions of Eq. (12) (see Hirsch et al. 2013) and in order to perform the local analysis leading to Table 1.
We conclude that when using adaptive dynamics to model a trait that is restricted to an interval (for biological reasons), points on the boundary of this interval may be ES, despite not being singular points. More care is thus required to examine the dynamics of such models near boundary points.
Appendix 3: The assumption that contribution is measured in units of fitness cost, \(c(h)=h\)
In this appendix, we comment on the biological interpretation of our assumption that the contribution of the focal agent is measured in units of the fitness cost it incurs, \(c\left( h,H\right) = h\) (Eq. (2)).
Suppose, as before, that the population is engaged in an n-player public goods game, and let \(h_1,\dots , h_n\) be the contributions of all the members of the focal agent’s group, including the focal agent (for example, if the index of the focal agent is \(i=1\), then \(h=h_1\)).
Thus, substituting
in Eq. (4), we have
However, we relax our assumption in Eq. (2) and instead only assume that
so that the fitness cost incurred by the focal agent is independent of the contributions of the other members in its group.
The focal agent’s fitness is then
For \(1\le i \le n\), let \(C_i=c(h_i)\), and \(C= c(h)\) be the costs incurred by the n members of the focal agent’s group, and the focal agent (respectively). Suppose that the cost function is one-to-one, so that there exists a left-inverse function \(k(\cdot )\) satisfying \(k\big (c(h)\big ) = h\) and \(k\big (c(h_i)\big ) = h_i\) for all \(1\le i \le n\). Then, Eq. (59) becomes
The benefit to the focal agent, \(f\left( \sum _{i=1}^{n} k(C_i) \right) \) is then generally not a function of the sum of the group members’ fitness costs, \(\sum _{i=1}^{n} C_i\).
By assuming that contributions to the public good are expressed in units of fitness cost (i.e., \(c(h)=h\), as in Eq. (2)), we implicitly assumed that fitness itself is the public good. Expressed in more biological terms, we are assuming that reproductive costs are effectively transferable: each individual in a group obtains a fitness benefit \(f(\eta )\) regardless of how the associated costs (which sum to \(\eta \)) are distributed among the group members; for example, the fitness benefit is the same if the focal agent contributes the entire cost (\(h=\eta \)), or if the cost is distributed equally among group members (\(h_i=\eta /n\) for each i).
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Molina, C., Earn, D.J.D. Evolutionary stability in continuous nonlinear public goods games. J. Math. Biol. 74, 499–529 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00285-016-1017-1
Received:
Revised:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00285-016-1017-1