Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Trends in tax revenues of transition economies: an empirical approach

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Economic theory postulates that taxes and alternative tax policies have different impacts on economic growth. Some scholars have argued that economic growth can result in an increase in total tax revenues and its ratio to GDP. Our study investigates the impact of economic growth on total tax revenues and different tax share ratios in transitional economies. We find strong support for the hypothesis that economic growth leads to an increase in total tax revenue-to-GDP ratio. We also find that economic growth has led to, and facilitated, changes in the relative shares of different tax sources in transition countries over time differently thus allowing these countries to streamline their taxes and properly plan for and alter their tax system accordingly.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

Additional information on data and sources of data are available from the authors upon request.

Notes

  1. To calculate real openness, the following formula, proposed by Alcala and Ciccone (2004: 613) was utilized: \(Real Opennes{s}_{AC}=\frac{Imports \left(\$\right)+Exports (\$)}{GDP PPP, \$}\).

  2. We ran instrumental-variable GMM estimations to ensure robustness of our results. Taking first differences we obtain dynamic model: $$\Delta  ln\text{ }{\tau }_{it}={\beta }_{0}+{\beta }_{1}\text{\Delta  }\mathit{ln} {Y}_{it-1}+{\sum }_{i,t=1}^{k}{\eta }_{i}{\text{\Delta }Z\text{'}}_{i,  t-1}+({\alpha }_{i}-\text{ }{\alpha }_{i})+\text{\Delta }{\varepsilon }_{it}$$. To find a set of instruments that satisfy $$E\left({Z}_{it}\text{\Delta }{\varepsilon }_{it}\right)=0$$, in addition to using all available lag levels for the first difference equation as per Arellano and Bond (1991), we constructed Anderson-Hsiao estimator to the first-differenced equation, instrumenting the lagged dependent variable with the twice-lagged level: $${\tau }_{i(t-2)}$$ and $$\Delta {\tau }_{i(t-2)}$$ as per Judson and Owen (1999). The estimations of extended models for difference GMM and system GMM are reported in Appendix II.

  3. While we kept fixed-effects (within) regression with robust standard errors clustered at the country level as our baseline model estimation, our extended model relied on first difference GMM and system GMM transformation as in our panel sample T < N, i.e. fewer time periods than number of countries.

  4. Election year is defined as an election year of either president or a prime-minister, or whoever of these two posts who acts as a head of state in our sample of countries.

Abbreviations

CIT:

Corporate Income Tax

HIC:

High-income countries

FEM:

Fixed-effect model

GDP:

Gross Domestic Product

GNP:

Gross National Product

LIC:

Low-income countries

MIC:

Middle-income countries

OECD:

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development

PIT:

Personal Income Tax

SSC:

Social Security Contributions

VAT:

Value-Added Tax

References

  • Abizadeh S (1979) Tax ratio and the degree of economic development. Singapore Econ Rev 24(1):21–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Acosta-Ormaechea S, Yoo J (2012) Tax composition and growth: a broad cross-country perspective. IMF working paper 12/257

  • Alcala F, Ciccone A (2004) Trade and productivity. Q J Econ 119(2):613–646

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiel L, Deller S, Stallmann J (2012) Economic growth and tax and expenditure limitations. Rev Reg Stud 42:185–206

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold J (2008) Do tax structures affect aggregate economic growth? Empirical evidence from a panel of OECD countries. OECD Economics Department Working Papers 643. OECD Publishing. https://doi.org/10.1787/236001777843

  • Baltagi BH (2008) Econometrics. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Sala-i-Martin X (1992) Convergence. J Polit Econ 100:223–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cass D (1965) Optimum growth in an aggregate model of capital accumulation. Rev Econ Stud 32:233–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dollar D, Kraay A (2003) Institutions, trade, and growth. J Monet Econ 50:133–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf SN, Johnson PA, Temple JRW (2005) Growth econometrics. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SN (eds) Handbook of economic growth. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 566–677

    Google Scholar 

  • Engen EM, Skinner J (1999) Taxation and economic growth. In: Slemrod J (ed) Tax policy in the real world. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 305–330

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ferraresi M (2021) Political budget cycle, tax collection mimicking and yardstick competition. BE J Econ Anal Policy. https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2020-0380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Romer D (1999) Does trade cause growth? Am Econ Rev 89(3):379–399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehlbach S (2008) Representation through taxation revenue, politics, and development in post-communist states. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gerson P (1998) The impact of fiscal policy variables on output growth. IMF working paper 98/1. International Monetary Fund, Washington DC

  • Golden M, Min B (2013) Distributive politics around the world. Annu Rev Polit Sci 16:73–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinrichs H (1966) A general theory of tax structure change during economic development. Harvard University, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsiao C (2003) Analysis of panel data. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Keely LC, Quah D (2000) Technology in growth. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Judson RA, Owen AL (1999) Estimating dynamic panel data models: a practical guide for macroeconomics. Econ Lett 65(1):9–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans TC (1965) On the concept of optimal economic growth. In: Koopmans TC (ed) The econometric approach to development planning. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 225–287

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahdavi S (2008) The level and composition of tax revenue in developing countries: evidence from unbalanced panel data. Int Rev Econ Finance 17:607–617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulton BR (1987) Diagnostics for group effects in regression analysis. J Bus Econ Stat 5(2):275–282

    Google Scholar 

  • Nijkamp P, Poot J (1998) Spatial perspectives on new theories of economic growth. Ann Region Sci 32:7–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey F (1928) Empirics for economic growth and convergence. Eur Econ Rev 40:543–559

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D, Rodriguez F (1999) Trade policy and economic growth: a sceptic’s guide to the cross national evidence. Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper: 2143

  • Romer P (1986) Increasing returns and long run growth. J Polit Econ 94:1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobel RS, Holcombe RG (1996) Measuring the growth and variability of tax bases over the business cycles. Natl Tax J 49:535–552

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70:65–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanzi V (1992) Structural factors and tax revenue in developing countries: a decade of evidence. In: Goldin I, Winters LA (eds) Open economies: structural adjustment and agriculture. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 267–281

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Tarschys D (2003) Taxes and bribes: assessing the extraction burden in orderly and disorderly societies. Eur Rev 11(03):365–383

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tosun MS, Abizadeh S (2005) Economic growth and tax components: an analysis of tax changes in OECD countries. Appl Econ 37:2251–2263

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to two anonymous reviewers of the journal for their constructive comments and suggestions on the earlier version of this article.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sohrab Abizadeh.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Disclaimer: The views and opinions expressed in this academic article are those of the authors. They are not endorsed by the Public Service Commission of Canada or the Government of Canada.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Descriptive statistics and data definition

See Tables 2, 3, 4, 5 .

Table 2 Summary statistics of tax structure variables
Table 3 Summary statistics of control variables
Table 4 Data definition and sources
Table 5 Tax Structure Variables and Columns Abbreviations

Appendix 2: Results of diagnostic tests to ensure robustness of the empirical model

Please refer to footnotes 1 and 2 in the text for additional background on these results (Tables 6, 7).

Table 6 Estimation results: difference GMM
Table 7 Estimation results: system GMM

Appendix 3: The stationarity of tax variables and adf-unit root test results

To check for stationarity (or unit roots) of tax variables and GDP per capita growth in our panel dataset, the Fisher type panel-data unit-root tests are performed. Fisher-type unit-root tests for all tax and GDP variables are based on (a) Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test and (b) Phillips-Perron (PP) test. The null hypothesis of both the Fisher-ADF and the Fisher-PP unit root tests is that all panels contain a unit root or stationarity. The alternative hypothesis of the tests is that at least one panel is stationary. Panel-specific means (fixed effects) in the model are included, but time trend is excluded.

Lags (5) of the series are used in the Fisher-ADF and Fisher-PP regressions. The lags (5) are used to remove higher-order autoregressive components of the series. Thus, the assumption is that the data are generated by AR (5) process for Fisher tests:

$$\Delta \mathit{ln}{\tau }_{t}=\Delta ln T{R}_{t}-\Delta ln T{R}_{t-1}$$
(5)

The results of this test for all the tax variables and GDP per capita growth are given in Table 8. The first noticeable thing in this table is that almost all the estimated coefficients are individually highly significant, for the p-values are low. This gives us strong evidence against the null hypothesis in favor of the alternative (as p-values are mostly within the range of 0.001 < p < 0.01). These results confirm that the GDP per capita growth and tax variables are all stationary in their change or difference form.

Table 8 Tests for difference stationarity (Fisher-type unit-root test)

Furthermore, the test results indicate that all our dependent and explanatory variables in panel are stationary. Almost all variables in first differences pass the stationarity test at 1% significance level.

Appendix 4: Omitted variables test (model with political budget cycle and year of accession to the eu dummy variables)

To ensure that missing variable phenomenon has not biased the empirical results of our main regression models, we have deployed four dummies as proxies. For political budget cycle we use: (1) one year before election yearFootnote 4; (2) one year after election year; proxy for specific tax policies adopted by countries at different point in time. For membership in the European Union (EU) we use two dummies, namely—(3) year of EU accession; and (4) one year after EU accession, controlling for country fixed effects and time dummies.

When running regression with these dummies, we used one fewer dummy than the number of categories for any categorical variable to avoid collinearity using the following model:

$${\tau }_{it}={\beta }_{0}+{\beta }_{1}{\text{D}}_{1i}+{\beta }_{2}{D}_{2i}+ {\beta }_{3}{D}_{3i}+{{\beta }_{4}{D}_{4i}+ \beta {X}_{it}+\epsilon }_{it}$$
(6)

Then, we leave the intercept in (5) to make the model more robust and to obtain unbiased standard errors:

$${\tau }_{it}={\beta }_{1}{\text{D}}_{1i}+{\beta }_{2}{D}_{2i}+ {\beta }_{3}{D}_{3i}+{{\beta }_{4}{D}_{4i}+ \beta {X}_{it}+\epsilon }_{it}$$
(7)

where \({D}_{1i}=\text{PB }(\text{one year before election year dummy})\), \({D}_{2i}=PB+1 (\text{one year after election year dummy})\), \({D}_{3i}=\text{EU }(\text{EU accession year dummy})\), \({D}_{4i}=EU+1 (\text{one year after EU accession year dummy})\).

Equation (7) with added dummy variables is integrated with the tax structure grand regression (the main regression in columns 1 of Table 9 when re-running the model below:

$$\Delta ln {\tau }_{it}=\alpha +{\beta }_{1}\Delta \mathit{ln} {Y}_{it}+{\beta }_{2}\Delta ln {Z}_{it}\eta +{f}_{i}{D}_{i}+{\varphi }_{t}+{\varepsilon }_{it}$$
(8)
Table 9 Impact of control variables on overall tax collection. Period of 1991–2015

The regression results for Eq. (8) are presented in Table 9 below.

First and foremost, when comparing the results in Table 9 with those in column 1 of Table 5, the signs and significance of estimated coefficients for all the original explanatory variables are the same. These results confirm that our original model is robust in explaining the trends in overall tax revenues of the transition economies and new variables do not alter the conclusions arrived at based on that model. Nonetheless, introduction of both political budget cycle and year of membership in the EU dummies produce valuable information.

Specifically, the results in columns 1–4 of Table 9 suggests that the political budget cycle instruments represented in the form of dummy variables \({D}_{1i} \text{one year before election year}\) has a negative impact on tax revenue collection overall when a one-year pre-election year is plagued by political manipulation due to political budget cycle theory (Ferraressi 2021; Golden and Min, 2013). Consequently, fiscal tools such as overall tax revenues and various types of taxes are negatively affected. In contrast to that, \({D}_{2i}\) one year after election variable, has a positive and highly significant impact on the tax revenue collection, suggesting that after election to their respective office, political leaders tend to deviate from their tax reduction promises during the election and raise taxes.

The EU membership dummy variable \({D}_{3i}\) year of EU accession has a negative effect on collection of tax revenues in our sample, suggesting slightly lower revenues compared to the pre-accession period for new EU members. Such a decrease in tax revenues may suggest elimination of tax sources that were previously collected through the local channels that could not continue after EU accession. However, \({D}_{4i}\) one year after EU accession, shows a positive impact on overall tax collection for new EU member countries. This may be due to introducing new tax policies and tax sources to comply with the EU common fiscal regime.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Khujamkulov, I., Abizadeh, S. Trends in tax revenues of transition economies: an empirical approach. Empir Econ 64, 833–868 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-022-02269-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-022-02269-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation