1 Introduction

It is well known that macroeconomic volatility generates both economic and political uncertainty with detrimental effects on investment and consumption plans and, ultimately, future economic growth (Acemoglu et al. 2003) and aggregate welfare (Athanasoulis and van Wincop 2000). There is therefore considerable interest, among academics as well as policy-makers, in shedding light on the sources of output fluctuations, especially in the new economic environment characterised by a much greater role played by emerging market countries and by low growth and uncertainty in advanced economies.

Economic theory does not provide unequivocal predictions: International financial and trade linkages could result either in a higher or a lower degree of business cycle co-movement depending on whether or not demand- and supply-side (as well as wealth) effects dominate over increased specialisation of production through the reallocation of capital (Baxter and Kouparitsas 2005; Kose et al. 2003, 2012). This cannot be established ex-ante: It is essentially an empirical question.

A knowledge of cross-country spillover effects is, especially relevant for emerging countries because of their higher degree of volatility compared to more mature economies. According to Loayaza et al. (2007), both internal and external factors explain why emerging economies are so volatile: (1) the instrinsic instability induced by the development process itself; (2) the lack of effective mechanisms (such as well functioning financial markets and proper stabilisation macroeconomic policies) to absorb external fluctuations; and (3) the exposure to exogenous shocks in the form of sudden capital inflows/outflows and/or large changes in the international terms of trade.

The Latin American (LA) economies in particular have experienced a remarkable sequence of booms and busts in the last three decades. After the debt crisis of the 1980s, most countries in the region benefited from huge capital inflows (with a resulting high growth rate) until the Russian crisis in the late nineties led to their sudden drying up; then, in the early years of the following decade higher liquidity, a dramatic rise in commodity prices and low risk premia created a particularly favourable macroeconomic and financial environment in the region and generated again robust growth (Österholm and Zettelmeyer 2007; Izquierdo et al. 2008); therefore, the question has been asked whether there has been a decoupling of the business cycle in the industrialised countries and the LA region, respectively, the latter having become an increasingly autonomous source of growth for the world economy.

The present study assesses the relative importance of external as well as regional and country-specific factors in explaining business cycle fluctuations in the LA region as a whole over the last three decades. It also investigates the role of bilateral trade flows and financial linkages in business cycle co-movements between the LA region and its main economic partners. More specifically, the analysis is based on the framework introduced by Diebold and Yilmaz (2012) and uses a very flexible empirical model to examine the propagation of international business cycles without any restrictions on the directions of short- and long-run spillovers or the nature of the propagation mechanism itself.

Using quarterly data from 1980:I to 2011:IV, we document that the LA region can be characterised as a small open economy largely dependent on external developments. This applies, especially to the the years following the great recession of 2008 and 2009, contradicting the so-called decoupling hypothesis. In particular, our findings imply that the goods trade channel is the most important source of these linkages. Capital flows also affect business cycle co-movements, but their role is limited, especially in the very short run. The disaggregate analysis focusing on their components (debt, portfolio equity and foreign direct investment flows) reveals a negative effect of portfolio equity flows on the degree of business cycle synchronisation, as predicted by standard international real business cycle models with complete markets. By contrast, short-term capital and foreign direct investment flows reinforce in the short run the role of the trade channel and make the LA region more vulnerable to shocks from abroad, consistently with recent empirical evidence (e.g. Imbs 2010).

The layout of the paper is as follows. Section 2 describes the methodology used to assess the propagation mechanism of international business cycles. Section 3 describes the data and presents the empirical results based on the forecast error variance decompositions for the LA bloc. Section 4 provides evidence on the role of financial and trade linkages. Section 5 offers some concluding remarks. The “Appendix” provides further evidence for the individual LA economies.

2 The methodology

2.1 The empirical framework

We focus on output growth to analyse the dynamic relationships between the LA region and the rest of the world. Given the increasing degree of integration of the global economy, it is essential to consider possible linkages with a number of foreign economies. It is equally important to allow for time variation, since a fixed parameter model is not likely to capture possibly important changes in the business cycle propagation mechanisms resulting from globalisation.Footnote 1

Consequently, the modelling approach chosen here differs from previous ones in two ways. First, it is flexible enough to accommodate possible nonlinear shifts in the propagation of international business cycles; second, it is based on analysing linkages with the output growth rate of various economies outside the LA region rather than a number of macroeconomic variables for a single foreign country (typically the US). Therefore, we include the US as the main driving force behind business cycles co-movements in the LA region (see the literature on the US “backyard”, e.g. Ahmed 2003; Canova 2005; Caporale et al. 2011), but also the Euro area because of its historical trade linkages with the LA region, as well as Japan (given the financial linkages documented by Boschi 2012; Boschi and Girardi 2011) and China, whose trade linkages with the LA region have become much stronger in recent years (Cesa-Bianchi et al. 2011).

As in Diebold and Yilmaz (2012), the econometric framework is based on the following covariance-stationary Vector AutoRegression (VAR) model

$$\begin{aligned} y_{t}^{(k)} =\sum _{j=1}^p {\Gamma _j^{(k)}} y_{t-j}^{(k)} +u_{t}^{(k)} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

in its moving average representation

$$\begin{aligned} y_{t}^{(k)} =\sum _{j=0}^\infty {\Psi _j^{(k)}} u_{t-j}^{(k)} \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(\Psi _i^{(k)} =\sum _{j=1}^p {\Gamma _i^{(k)}} \Psi _{i-j}^{(k)} \), \(p\) is the order of autoregression, the vector \(y\) includes the \(n\) endogenous variables of the system, \(t=1,\ldots ,T\) indexes time, and \(e\) is the vector of residuals, with \(E[u_{t}^{(k)} ]=0\), \(E[u_{t}^{(k)} ,{u}_s^{'(k)} ]=\Sigma _{u}^{(k)} \) if \(s=t\) and \(E[u_{t}^{(k)} ,{u}_s^{'(k)} ]=0\) otherwise. All elements refer to the generic \(k\)th estimation sample with window size of \(\theta \le T\) observations, so that if \(\theta =T\) then \(k=1\), whilst if \(\theta <T\), model (1) involves \(k=T-\theta +1\) different rolling estimates, where the sample initially spans the period from the first available observation to \(\theta \), and then, both its starting and ending period is shifted forward by one datapoint at a time. As pointed out by Granger (2008), linear models with time-varying parameters are actually very general nonlinear models, and therefore, the chosen framework is ideally suited to analysing the issues of interest.

2.2 Innovation accounting

Examining all the effects of the lagged variables in a VAR model is often both difficult and unnecessary for the purposes of the analysis (Sims 1980). Rather, it is more convenient to resort to some transformations of the estimated model (1) in order to summarise the dynamic linkages among the \(n\) variables under investigation. In the business cycle literature, a useful metric often used to measure the extent of business cycle synchronisation is the sum of the variance shares of different classes of shocks such as country-specific, regional or global sources of economic fluctuations (see Kose et al. 2012, among others).Footnote 2

Since the reduced form residuals \(u\)’s are generally correlated, a common practice to obtain uncorrelated shocks is to use the Choleski decomposition of \(\Sigma _{u}^{(k)} \). Despite its straightforward implementation, this method has the drawback that it is sensitive to the ordering of the variables in the system, and therefore, all possible permutations should be considered when carrying out the dynamic simulations for a thorough assessment. A popular alternative is provided by the generalised forecast error variance (GFEV) decomposition (Pesaran and Shin 1998). This approach estimates the percentage of the variance of the \(h\)-step ahead forecast error of the variable of interest which is explained by conditioning on the non-orthogonalised shocks whilst explicitly allowing for contemporaneous correlations between these shocks and those to the other equations in the system

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {GFEV}_{l,m,h}^{(k)} =\frac{1}{\sigma _{m,m}^{(k)}}\sum _{q=0}^h {({e}'_l \Psi _q^{(k)} \Sigma _{u}^{(k)} e_{m}} )^{2} \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where the selection vectors \(e_l \) and \(e_{m}\) have their \(l\)th and \(m\)th entries equal to one, respectively, with all other elements being zero, and \(\sigma _{m,m}^{(k)} \) stands for the standard deviation associated to the \(m\)th equation of the system.

Although the GFEV method does not allow a structural interpretation of the impulses, it overcomes the identification problem by providing a meaningful characterisation of the dynamic responses of the variables of interest to observable shocks. A further useful feature of this approach is its invariance to the ordering of the variables. Note, however, that owing to the possible non-diagonal form of matrix \(\Sigma _{u}^{(k)} \), the sum over \(m\) of the elements (3) need not be unity in the original formulation provided by Pesaran and Shin (1998). In order to be able to interpret the results, we rescale (3) using the total variance in the generalised rather than in the orthogonal case

$$\begin{aligned} {\xi }_{l,m,h}^{(k)} =\frac{\frac{1}{\sigma _{m,m}^{(k)}}\sum _{q=0}^h {({e}'_l \Psi _q^{(k)} \Sigma _{u}^{(k)} e_{m}} )^{2}}{\sum _{m=1}^{n} {\frac{1}{\sigma _{m,m}^{(k)}}\sum _{q=0}^h {({e}'_l \Psi _q^{(k)} \Sigma _{u}^{(k)} e_{m}} )^{2}}} \end{aligned}$$
(4)

so that \(\sum _{m=1}^{n} {{\xi }_{l,m,h}^{(k)}} =1\) (for all \(k\) and \(h)\), that is, the sum of the variance decompositions in (4) are normalised to unity.

2.3 Measuring spillover effects

By computing the decomposition (4) for all variables in system (1) for a given recursion \(k\) and for a given simulation horizon \(h\), we obtain the following \(n\times n\) matrix (the spillover table according to the terminology of Diebold and Yilmaz 2012),Footnote 3 which makes it possible to measure to extent to which two or more variables of the system are connected to each other:

(5)

Diebold and Yilmaz (2012) show that a synthetic measure of the spillovers to (from) country \(l\) from (to) all other countries can be obtained by summing by columns (rows) all the off-diagonal elements in the \(l\)th row (column). We adapt their framework by dividing the variable of system (1) into two distinct subsets (which we label regional and external groups) with dimension of \(n_1 =6\) and \(n-n_1 =4\), respectively. More precisely, we define the region-specific shocks, \({\gamma }_{\mathrm{reg},h}^{(k)} \), as

$$\begin{aligned} {\gamma }_{\mathrm{reg},h}^{(k)} =\frac{1}{n_1 }\sum _{l=1}^{n_1 } {\sum _{m=1}^{n_1 } {{\xi }_{l,m,h}^{(k)}} } \end{aligned}$$
(6)

whilst the aggregate external shocks (that is, the innovations originating outside the LA region) are computed as

$$\begin{aligned} {\gamma }_{\mathrm{ext},h}^{(k)} =\frac{1}{n_1 }\sum _{l=1}^{n_1 } {\sum _{m=n_1 }^{n} {{\xi }_{l,m,h}^{(k)}} } \end{aligned}$$
(7)

i.e. both (6) and (7) are normalised so as to lie in the [0, 1] interval.

In order to identify the direction of the linkages between the two (aggregate) blocs of countries, we define the regional net spillover index, \({\gamma }_{\mathrm{net},h}^{(k)} \), as the difference between growth spillovers from and to others in terms of the elements belonging to the external bloc of the system

$$\begin{aligned} {\gamma }_{\mathrm{net},h}^{(k)} =\sum _{l=n_1 +1}^{n} {\sum _{m=1}^{n_1 } {{\xi }_{l,m,h}^{(k)}} } -\sum _{l=1}^{n_1 } {\sum _{m=n_1 +1}^{n} {{\xi }_{l,m,h}^{(k)}} } \end{aligned}$$
(8)

so that positive (negative) values for (8) indicate that the region is a net transmitter (receiver) to (from) outside (Diebold and Yilmaz 2012; Antonakakis and Badinger 2012). Using condition (8), it is straightforward to obtain a breakdown for the individual countries forming the external bloc, so that we can define \(n-n_1 \) pairwise regional net spillover indexes, \({\gamma }_{{cty},h}^{(k)} \), as

$$\begin{aligned} {\gamma }_{cty,h}^{(k)} =\sum _{m=1}^{n_1 } {{\xi }_{cty,m,h}^{(k)}} -\sum _{l=1}^{n_1 } {{\xi }_{cty,m,h}^{(k)}} \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where \(cty=n_1 +1,\ldots ,n\).

Before discussing the empirical findings, it is worth noting that the \(\gamma \)’s indices depend on the simulation span (through the index \(h)\) and on the estimation sample (through the index \(k)\). This is motivated by the need for a sufficiently flexible model specification to analyse the sources of business cycles in a period such as the recent one characterised by exceptionally large fluctuations.Footnote 4 Further, considering a wide range of simulation horizons enables us to obtain a dynamic picture of how cross-country business cycle linkages evolve when moving from the short to the long run through a sequence of GFEV decompositions for which the conditioning information is becoming progressively less important as the simulation horizon widens.Footnote 5

3 Assessing business cycle co-movements in the LA bloc

3.1 Data and preliminary analysis

We use quarterly real GDP series for six major LA countries (namely, Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Mexico, Peru and Venezuela) and for the four largest economies in the world (the US, the Euro area, Japan and China) over the period 1980:I–2011:IV.Footnote 6 The 10 chosen economies represent about 75 % of real world GDP, with the six LA countries included representing approximately 85 % of real GDP in the LA region over the period 1980–2010 according to the World Development Indicator data.

As a preliminary step, we test for the presence of unit roots in the GDP series in logarithms. ADF tests are performed, both on the levels and the first differences of the series. In each case, we are unable to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root in the levels at conventional significance levels. On the other hand, differencing the series appears to induce stationarity. Standard stationarity tests corroborate this conclusion.Footnote 7

Given the nonstationarity of the time series and the lack of an economic theory suggesting the number of long-run relationships and/or how they should be interpreted, it is reasonable not to impose the restriction of cointegration on a VAR model (Ramaswamy and Sloek 1998). Thus, we have opted for a specification in first differences since the focus of our analysis is on (time-varying) short-run linkages rather than secular trends (as, for instance, in Bernard and Durlauf 1995).

We choose size 80 for the rolling windows (i.e. 20 years of quarterly observations, 80 observations in all). This can be regarded as a compromise between stability and flexibility, as it turned out that a smaller window size makes the VAR models more unstable.Footnote 8 Such a choice implies that the complete set of recursions produces 48 different sets of VAR estimates.Footnote 9 The GFEV decomposition analysis is then conducted over a simulation horizon of 20 quarters (5 years).

3.2 Empirical evidence

The variance decomposition for the LA region is computed as an (equally weighted) average of individual country-specific figures.Footnote 10 According to Eqs. (6) and (7), it is based on a synthetic economy which is an “average” LA country, as in Izquierdo et al. (2008). Figure 1 shows the decomposition of the output variance into region-specific (Panel A) and external sources (Panel B).

Fig. 1
figure 1

LA region: region-specific versus external factors. Note In each tri-dimensional graph, the horizontal plane is spanned by the temporal horizon and the simulation steps, whilst the vertical axis measures the intensity of the indicators given by conditions (6) and (7)

Regarding the regional sources of fluctuations, their relative importance vis-à-vis the external ones appears to diminish over the simulation horizon. The dominant role of external factors in the long run is found for all quarters. In particular, external factors account for about 30 % of the long-run (20-quarter horizon) variance of LA GDP growth, consistently with the evidence in Österholm and Zettelmeyer (2007) and in Aiolfi et al. (2010).

As for the evolution over time of the estimated effects, the relative contribution of the two types of factors is remarkably stable up to the first half of 2008. With the onset of the global crisis, external factors appear to acquire an increasing role, especially at the very bottom of the global downturn (between mid-2008 and mid-2009), accounting for more than 50 % of total variability in 2008:IV. Subsequently, following a partial recovery, idiosyncratic factors have regained some (but not all) of their former importance. Our findings therefore give support to previous evidence according to which the LA region is still characterised by heavy dependence on external factors and does not carry sufficient weight to affect the international business cycle with its own growth dynamics (Calvo et al. 1993; Izquierdo, 2008; Cesa-Bianchi et al. 2011), thus contradicting the so-called decoupling hypothesis (Helbling et al. 2007).

Further evidence is presented in Fig. 2, which shows the difference between growth spillovers to and from the external bloc of the system as defined by (8). There is a predominance of negative values for the rolling estimates (especially when considering long-run effects), suggesting that the LA region can be characterised as a net receiver. This applies even more strongly to the recovery period after the peak of the global crisis: The long-run net effect, after reaching a minimum of \(-\)17 % in 2008:IV, is about \(-\)8 % at the end of the sample.

Fig. 2
figure 2

LA region: net effects (region-specific minus external factors). Note In each tri-dimensional graph, the horizontal plane is spanned by the temporal horizon and the simulation steps, whilst the vertical axis measures the intensity of the indicator as defined by condition (8). Positive (negative) values indicate that growth spillovers to external countries are greater (lower) than those from them

However, net spillover effects vis-à-vis an aggregate “rest of the world” could hide underlying heterogeneity, which can only be detected by a more disaggregate analysis. Figure 3 presents the net pairwise spillover effects between the LA region and the US (Panel A), the Euro area (Panel B), Japan (Panel C) and China (Panel D).

Fig. 3
figure 3

LA region: net effects (region-specific minus individual foreign country factors). Note In each tri-dimensional graph, the horizontal plane is spanned by the temporal horizon and the simulation steps, whilst the vertical axis measures the intensity of the indicator given by condition (9)

Both short- and long-run effects appear to be very stable, especially in the case of China. In particular, the balance between growth spillovers to and from the outside world is negative for the LA region in most cases. This is largely true for the years of the great recession (2007–2009), during which the LA region suffered from the recessionary impulses coming from the most advanced economies (but not from China). In the most recent years, however, the overall picture seems to have changed significantly, namely the impact of business cycle conditions in the US, the Euro area and Japan has diminished, whilst the influence of the Chinese economy has increased. Overall, the disaggregate results provide no evidence of de-coupling; they also indicate that bilateral linkages with China have become stronger, making the LA region vulnerable not only to economic hardship in the industrialised economies but also to future developments in China, as already pointed out by Cesa-Bianchi et al. (2011).

4 Determinants of the linkages between the LA region and the world economy

4.1 The role of trade and capital flows

Since the study of Frankel and Rose (1998) a considerable body of empirical research (Kalemli-Ozcan et al. 2009; Imbs 2010; Caporale et al. 2014) has shown that bilateral trade flows (\(tra)\) and financial linkages (\(fin)\) can affect business cycles correlations (\(\uprho )\) across countries and/or regions, following this literature, a canonical regression model can be specified as

$$\begin{aligned} \rho ={\psi }_{1} +{\psi }_{2} tra+{\psi }_{3} fin+\varepsilon \end{aligned}$$
(10)

The positive effect of bilateral trade flows on the degree of international business cycle synchronisation has been widely established in that literature and is consistent with the theoretical predictions of the model developed by Kose and Yi (2006). As for capital flows, several studies give support to the view that financial integration increases the degree of business cycle correlations in cross sections and over time (Imbs 2010), whilst other papers (e.g. Kalemli-Ozcan et al. 2009) find that financially integrated economies have negative co-movements, as posited by standard international real business cycle models with complete markets (Backus et al. 1994). The sign for \({\psi }_3 \) in (13) is thus the object of empirical scrutiny.Footnote 11

We follow Frankel and Rose (1998) and compute (a time variant version of) bilateral trade intensities as

$$\begin{aligned} {\textit{tra}}_{t} =\frac{X_{l,e,t} +X_{e,l,t}}{Y_{l,t} +Y_{e,t}} \end{aligned}$$

where \(X_{l,e,t} \) denote total merchandise exports from the LA region (\(l)\) to the external bloc (\(e)\), \(X_{e,l,t} \) are exports from the aggregate foreign economy to the LA region, \(Y_{l,t} \) and \(Y_{e,t} \) are the GDP nominal levels in the two economies, and \(t\) is a time index.

As for capital flows between the two blocs, these are proxied as

$$\begin{aligned} {\textit{fin}}_{t} =\left| {\frac{\hbox {NFA}_{l,t}}{Y_{l,t}}-\frac{\hbox {NFA}_{e,t}}{Y_{e,t}}} \right| \end{aligned}$$

where \(\hbox {NFA}_{l,t} \) and \(\hbox {NFA}_{e,t} \) stand for the (multilateral) net foreign asset position in the two aggregate economies. The rationale for this proxy is that capital should flow between countries or regions with different external positions: bilateral flows between two countries with the same net position should be less than between countries with opposite positions (Imbs (2003)). In particular, we compute the net foreign asset position as the sum of net positions in debt (dbt), equities (eqt) and foreign direct investment (fdi).Footnote 12

4.2 Estimation results

Using spillover indexes rather than standard correlation coefficients makes it possible to analyse (time-varying) business cycle correlations in a much more flexible framework by distinguishing between co-movements at different forecast horizons. To see this, we start by mapping our spillover index to the (time-varying) correlation coefficients. Following Forbes and Rigobon (2002), we consider the following least square regression between output growth rates of countries \(a\) and \(b\), \(\Delta y_a =a+b\Delta y_b +u\), so that

$$\begin{aligned} \uprho =\left[ {\frac{b^{2}\sigma _b^2 }{\sigma _a^2 }} \right] ^{0.5}\quad \hbox {or}\quad \frac{\uprho }{b}=\left[ {\frac{\sigma _b^2 }{\sigma _a^2 }} \right] ^{0.5} \end{aligned}$$
(11)

The term in square brackets on the RHS of the second expression in (11) is the share of output growth variability of country \(a\) explained by \(b\). In terms of our framework, it is expressed by \({\gamma }_\mathrm{ext} \) in (10). Condition (11) implies that \({{\rho }^{*}={\rho } }/b=\sqrt{{\gamma }_\mathrm{ext}}\) (for a given forecast horizon). Accordingly, Eq. (10) can be rewritten as follows

$$\begin{aligned} {\rho }_h^*={\alpha }_1^*+{\alpha }_2^*tra+{\alpha }_3^*{\textit{fin}}+{\varepsilon }^{*} \end{aligned}$$
(12)

where \(\alpha _i^*={\alpha _i }/b\), \(i=1,\ldots ,3\), \(\varepsilon =\varepsilon /b\) provided that \(b\ne 0\). As \({\gamma }_\mathrm{ext} \) is computed over a number of different simulation steps, \(h\), condition (12) can be tested at several forecast horizons in order to assess whether and how the role of trade and financial linkages varies according to \(h\). In what follows, we consider selected simulation horizons (namely, \(h=1,2,4,8,12,20)\).

The first step of the empirical analysis is based on standard correlation measures between \({\uprho }^{*}\) and its main macroeconomic determinants. Table 1 shows that the unconditional correlation coefficients for the \({\uprho }^{*}\)’s and \(tra\) variables are positive and statistically significant for all forecast horizons considered, confirming the well-established finding that higher business cycle synchronisation is associated with stronger trade intensity. One might argue that the positive correlation is spurious owing to the existence of factors correlated to both variables. When conditioning on \({\textit{fin}}\), the magnitude (and the statistical significance) of the partial correlation coefficients remains virtually unchanged. By contrast, the unconditional correlation between \({\uprho }^{*}\)’s and fin turn out to be statistically insignificant. The same conclusion holds when considering the partial measure of association (conditioned on tra), even though the sign of the relationship in general becomes negative.

Table 1 Correlation analysis: business cycle co-movements vs trade and capital flows

Correlations are only partially informative as they cannot gauge causality between the regressand and the explanatory covariates. In order to delve deeper into the effects of bilateral trade and capital flows on business cycle synchronisation, we estimate Eq. (12) by 2SLS for the chosen simulation horizons.Footnote 13 In order to control for the collapse (and the subsequent abrupt recovery) in trade flows which occurred during the 2008–2009 crisis, we augment the set of regressors by a crisis dummy (\(dum)\) taking the value of \(-\)1 in 2008:III and 2008:IV and \(+\)1 in 2009:I and 2009:II.Footnote 14

Table 2 presents the estimation results of the baseline specification.Footnote 15 Single, double or triple asterisks denote statistically significant coefficients at the 1, 5 or 10 % level, respectively. We also report robust standard errors (in parentheses) as well as some basic diagnostics for the chosen instruments (\(J\) statistics), the serial correlation of the residuals (\(DW)\) and the goodness of fit of the regression (\(R_\mathrm{adj}^2 )\).

Table 2 Business cycle co-movements, trade intensity and aggregate capital flows

The estimation results indicate a clear dominance of trade flows over financial linkages as the main determinant of business cycle co-movements between the LA region and the foreign bloc, even controlling for the trade collapse in 2008–2009: The coefficient of bilateral trade intensity is positive and statistically significant at all simulation steps; moreover, it increases almost monotonically with \(h\). Capital flows reduce the degree of co-movement between cycles, but the coefficients of \(fin\) are generally small in magnitude and imprecisely estimated.

Overall, these findings show that in the presence of relatively weak financial linkages, propagation of the impulses from outside to the LA bloc has taken place mainly through trade flows. The apparent de-coupling of the LA bloc from the most advanced economies thus arises not only from trade being increasingly oriented towards China rather than its historical trading partners (namely the US and the Euro area—see Cesa-Bianchi et al. (2011) but also from a low degree of financial integration with the rest of the world economy.

4.3 Extensions

In this Section, we present the results from a disaggregate analysis based on a breakdown of capital flows into debt, equity and FDI flows with the aim of shedding light on what type of flows are behind stronger business cycle co-movements.

We first assess the role of these components by replacing \(fin\) with disaggregated capital flows (entering the model individually). The results in Table 3 indicate that the trade channel, albeit dominant, is not the only one: Capital flows can also affect the degree of international business cycle synchronisation in the short run (namely, up to the fourth simulation step). Moreover, portfolio equity flows have a negative effect on the degree of business cycle synchronisation whilst that of debt and foreign direct investment is positive.

Table 3 Business cycle co-movements, trade intensity and sub-components of capital flows

As a further step, we consider a specification where the three types of flows enter the model simultaneously (Table 4). Over the first year of the simulation horizon, its explanatory power is higher with respect to its (nested) counterparts in Tables 2 and 3, suggesting that debt, portfolio equity and foreign direct investment act as additional channels of transmission of shocks from abroad.

Table 4 Business cycle co-movements, trade intensity and disaggregate capital flows

Our findings complement previous evidence for emerging markets according to which both trade and financial variables mattered prior to the global crisis (Blanchard et al. 2010), since we document that these factors largely explain business cycle co-movements over the last decade. However, our framework makes it possible to go further and to highlight the relative strength of the different transmission channels in the short and long run: The increasing explanatory power of trade flows over the entire simulation span is largely corroborated, whereas capital flows affect business cycle co-movement in the short-term, as the \(R_\mathrm{adj}^2 \) statistics show.Footnote 16 Moreover, in the very short-term debt and foreign direct investment have an opposite effect compared to equity portfolio flows. Whilst the result for \(eqt\) can be rationalised within the standard international real business cycle framework with complete markets, our findings for \(dbt\) and \(fdi\) suggest that short-term capital flows and internationalisation of production through foreign direct investment may strengthen the role of trade channel making the LA region more prone to suffer from the propagation of shocks from abroad.

5 Conclusions

This paper uses the econometric approach of Diebold and Yilmaz (2012) to analyse the extent to which business cycle developments in the LA region and the four largest economies in the world (the US, the Euro area, Japan and China) were connected over the period 1980:I–2011:IV.

We document that the LA region as a whole is strongly dependent on external developments. This conclusion holds, especially for the years after the great recession of 2008 and 2009, ruling out any decoupling of the LA region from the rest of the world. More specifically, we find a clear dominance of trade flows over financial linkages as a determinant of business cycle co-movements between the LA region and the foreign bloc. The apparent de-coupling of the LA area with respect to the most advanced economies in recent years thus seems to have been determined not only by increasing trade flows towards China but also by a low degree of financial integration with its main economic partners.

The decomposition of capital flows into their components (debt, portfolio equity and foreign direct investment flows) shows a negative effect of portfolio equity flows on the degree of business cycle synchronisation, consistently with the predictions of standard international real business cycle models with complete markets. In contrast, short-term capital and foreign direct investment flows tend to reinforce in the short run the role of the trade channel and the responsiveness of the LA region to external developments.