1 Introduction

Recent decades have shown a rapid growth of worldwide foreign direct investment (FDI), which led to increased efforts in research to understand the economic determinants of FDI activities. Classical explanations focus on the factors driving firms to become multinational. The Ownership-Localization-Internalization theory (see Dunning 2001) explains firms’ motivation as an effort to internalize transaction costs and reap the benefits of externalities stemming from strategic assets.

A large alternative strand of empirical literature builds on trade theory. In this context the drivers of FDI activity are the need for larger sales markets, cheaper source markets, and the willingness to reach a technological frontier (Markusen 1995). Following empirical international economics literature, FDI flows are usually captured within the context of a bilateral spatial interaction model framework. The main advantage of this approach is that it specifically accounts for the role of origin- and destination-specific factors, as well as intervening opportunities. For an overview on the determinants of FDI activities and the location choice of multinationals, see Basile and Kayam (2015), Blonigen and Piger (2014), or Blonigen (2005).

Due to the scarcity of data on FDI activities on a subnational scale, the vast majority of the empirical literature focuses on country-specific FDI patterns. A subnational perspective, however, would allow for in-depth decomposition of the spatial patterns of FDI flows, since FDI sources and destinations are not uniformly distributed within a country, but tend to be spatially clustered. Multiple studies focusing on regional investment decisions of multinational companies (Crescenzi et al. 2013; Ascani et al. 2016a; Krisztin and Piribauer 2020) emphasize within-country heterogeneity of FDI decisions, which can exceed cross-country differences. However, a major gap in the literature is that regional level studies only focus on the destination of FDI decisions, and largely neglect to account for origin-specific factors, as well as intervening opportunities in a subnational context. However, a simultaneous treatment appears particularly important for providing a complete picture on third-regional spatial interrelationships in both source- as well as destination-specific characteristics (Leibrecht and Riedl 2014). Moreover, neglecting to take into account both origin, destination, and third region effects, can lead to biased parameter estimates (Baltagi et al. 2007).

The present paper aims to fill these gaps by focusing on subnational FDI flows in a European multi-regional framework and explicitly accounting for origin-, destination-, as well as third region-specific factors. In this paper, we make use of subnational data from the fDi Markets database, which reports on bilateral FDI flows, with detailed information on the source and destination city. This can be compiled to multiple dyadic format, that is each region pair appears twice, corresponding to FDI flowing from one region to the other and vice versa. A specific virtue of the database is that it distinguishes FDI flows by their respective business activity. This allows us to contrast the impact of origin, destination, and third region effects across multiple stages of the global values chain.

Origin- and destination-specific third region effects are captured in our empirical model in two ways. First, the model specification contains spatial contextual effects by means of spatially lagged explanatory variables (see Regelink and Elhorst 2015). Second, we moreover employ an econometric framework in the spirit of Koch and LeSage (2015) and LeSage et al. (2007) which captures spatial dependence using spatially-augmented random effects.

When adopting a subnational perspective, it is crucial to control for spatial dependence, as its presence in regional data is well documented (LeSage and Pace 2009). Even national-level empirical applications clearly document the presence of spatial spillovers on FDI activities. An influential example is the work by Blonigen et al. (2007), who analyse the determinants of US outbound FDI activities in a cross-country framework, while explicitly accounting for spatial dependence among destinations. Further studies which document the presence of spatial issues amongst bilateral (national) FDI activities include Pintar et al. (2016), Regelink and Elhorst (2015), Chou et al. (2011), Garretsen and Peeters (2009), Poelhekke and van der Ploeg (2009), or Baltagi et al. (2007).

We therefore employ a spatial augmented Bayesian Poisson specification on the pan-European subnational level which aims at dealing with both orgin- and destination-specific characteristics. Estimation is achieved using work by Frühwirth-Schnatter et al. (2009), allowing us to deal with high-dimensional specifications in a flexible and computationally efficient way.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the proposed spatial interaction model, which is augmented by spatial autoregressive origin- and destination-specific random effects, intended to capture spatially dependencies, as well as so-called third region effects. Section 3 details the FDI data, the considered determinants, as well as our selection of regions. In Sect. 4 we assess the determinants of European interregional FDI flows across different stages of the global value chain. The analysis is performed using information on FDI dyads covering 266 NUTS-2 regions in the period 2003–2011. Section 5 concludes.

2 A spatial interaction model for subnational FDI flows

This section presents the model specification used for the empirical analysis. It is worth noting that the spatial econometric model is similar to work by LeSage et al. (2007), who aimed at modelling regional knowledge spillovers in Europe. An efficient Bayesian estimation approach for the employed multiplicative form of the Poisson model with spatial random effects is provided in the Appendix.Footnote 1

Let \(\varvec{y}\) denote an \(N \times 1\) vector containing information on the number of FDI flows between n regions.Footnote 2 In the classic spatial interaction model framework the flows are regressed on correspondingly stacked origin-, destination-, and distance-specific explanatory variables, as well as their spatially lagged counterparts. \(\varvec{X}_o\) and \(\varvec{X}_d\) denote \(N \times p_X\) origin- and destination-specific matrices of explanatory variables, respectively. Distances and further intervening factors between the n regions are captured by the \(N \times p_D\) matrix \(\varvec{D}\).Footnote 3 Extending the standard model specification with local spillover effects as well as spatial random effects, we consider a Poisson specification of the form:

$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{y}&\sim \mathcal {P}(\varvec{\lambda }) \nonumber \\ \varvec{\lambda }&= \exp \left( \alpha _0 + \varvec{X}_o \varvec{\beta }_o + \varvec{X}_d \varvec{\beta }_d + \varvec{D} \varvec{\gamma }_D + \varvec{W}_o \varvec{X}_o \varvec{\delta }_o + \varvec{W}_d \varvec{X}_d \varvec{\delta }_d +\varvec{V}_o\varvec{\theta }_o + \varvec{V}_d\varvec{\theta }_d \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(2.1)

where \(\mathcal {P}(\cdot )\) denotes the Poisson distribution and \(\alpha _0\) is an intercept parameter. \(\varvec{\beta }_o\), \(\varvec{\beta }_d\), and \(\varvec{\gamma }_D\) are parameter vectors corresponding to \(\varvec{X}_o\), \(\varvec{X}_d\), and \(\varvec{D}\), respectively. The spatial lags of the covariates are captured by \(\varvec{W}_o \varvec{X}_o\) and \(\varvec{W}_d \varvec{X}_d\), with \(\varvec{\delta }_o\) and \(\varvec{\delta }_d\) denoting the respective \(p_X \times 1\) vectors of parameters. Through these spatial lags we explicitly capture the so-called third region effects (Baltagi et al. 2007), that is origin- and destination-specific spillovers from neighbouring regions. Neighbourhood effects are governed by non-negative, row-stochastic spatial weight matrices, which contain information on the spatial connectivity between the regions under scrutiny. Our Poisson spatial interaction model includes separate spatial weight matrices \(\varvec{W}_o\) and \(\varvec{W}_d\) to account for origin- and destination-specific third regional effects, respectively.

Origin-based random effects are captured by the term \(\varvec{V}_o\varvec{\theta }_o\), where \(\varvec{V}_o\) denotes an \(N\times n\) matrix of origin-specific dummy variables with a corresponding \(n \times 1\) vector \(\varvec{\theta }_o\). Similarly, the \(n \times 1\) vector \(\varvec{\theta }_d\) captures regional effects associated with the destination regions’ matrix of dummy variables \(\varvec{V}_d\). We follow work by LeSage et al. (2007) and introduce a further source of spatial dependence via the \(n \times 1\) regional effect vectors \(\varvec{\theta }_o\) and \(\varvec{\theta }_d\), which are assumed to follow a first-order spatial autoregressive process:

$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{\theta }_o&= \rho _o \varvec{W} \varvec{\theta }_o + \varvec{\nu }_o \varvec{\nu }_o = \mathcal {N}\left( \varvec{0},\phi _o^2 \varvec{I}_n \right) \end{aligned}$$
(2.2)
$$\begin{aligned} \varvec{\theta }_d&= \rho _d \varvec{W} \varvec{\theta }_d + \varvec{\nu }_d \varvec{\nu }_d = \mathcal {N}\left( \varvec{0},\phi _d^2 \varvec{I}_n \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(2.3)

where \(\rho _o\) and \(\rho _d\) denote origin- and destination-specific spatial autoregressive (scalar) parameters, respectively. \(\varvec{W}\) denotes an \(n\times n\) row-stochastic spatial weight matrix with known constants and zeros on the main diagonal.

The disturbance error vectors \(\varvec{\nu }_o\) and \(\varvec{\nu }_d\) are both assumed to be independently and identically normally distributed, with zero mean and \(\phi _o^2\) and \(\phi _d^2\) variance, respectively. Note that this assumption implies a one-to-one mapping to origin- and destination-specific normally distributed random effects in the case of \(\rho _o = 0\) and \(\rho _d = 0\). For a row-stochastic \(\varvec{W}\), a sufficient stability condition may be employed by assuming the spatial autoregressive parameters \(\rho _o\) and \(\rho _d\) to lie in the interval \(-1< \rho _o, \rho _d < 1\) (see, for example, LeSage and Pace 2009).

3 Bilateral FDI data and regions

Our data set comprises observations on regional FDI dyads for 266 European NUTS-2 regions in the period 2003–2011. A complete list of the regions in our sample is provided in Table 6 in the Appendix.

Observations on regional cross-border greenfield FDI investments stem from the fDi Markets database. This database is maintained by fDi Intelligence, which is a specialist division of the Financial Times Ltd. The provided data draws on media and corporate sources to report on the sources and hosts of FDI flows (detailed by country, region, and city), industry classifications, as well as the level of capital investment. Crescenzi et al. (2013) report several robustness tests and detailed comparisons with official data sources. They confirm the reliability of the fDi Markets data set, especially with regard to the reported spatial distribution of FDI investments.

Our dependent variables are based on the total amount of inflows from European regions in the period 2003 to 2011. Since the fDi Markets data base also contains information on several distinct business activities for both origin and host companies, we follow previous studies by Ascani et al. (2016a) and study the determinants of regional FDI dyads at different stages of the value chain. This information is valuable as investor companies maximize their utility with respect to their position along the value chain. Since specifics of the investor company, as well as details on the FDI investment are largely unobserved, it is crucial to account for the heterogeneity in investor decisions by subdividing industry activities relative to their position along the value chain (see, for example, Ascani et al. 2016a). We therefore define three different classifications: Upstream, Downstream, and Production. The classification adopted in this paper builds on general classifications of the value chain by Sturgeon (2008) and closely tracks the ones employed by Crescenzi et al. (2013) and Ascani et al. (2016a).

Specifically, the upstream category comprises conceptual product development including design and testing, as well as management and business administration activities. The downstream category summarizes consumer-related activities such as sales, product delivery, or support. Finally, the production category includes activities related to physical product creation, including extraction, manufacturing, as well as recycling activities. A complete list of the employed global value chain classification is provided in Table 5 in the Appendix.

Our choices for explanatory variables are motivated by recent literature on (regional) FDI flows as well as regional growth empirics (see, for example, Crespo Cuaresma et al. 2018; Blonigen and Piger 2014; Leibrecht and Riedl 2014; or Blonigen 2005). In most gravity-type models, a region’s ability to emit and attract FDI flows is chiefly captured by its economic characteristics. Our main indicator for economic characteristics is the regions’ market size, proxied by regional gross value added. To control for the degree of urbanization both in origin and host regions, we also include regional population densities as an additional covariate. Empirical evidence suggests (Coughlin et al. 1991; Huber et al. 2017) that higher wages have a deterrent effect on investment. We proxy this in our model by including the average compensation of employees per hour worked as an explanatory variable.

We account for the regional industry mix by including the share of employment in manufacturing and construction (NACE classifications B to F), as well as services (NACE G to U). We moreover include typical supply-side quantities such as regional endowments of human and knowledge capital. To proxy regional human capital endowments, we include two different variables. The first variable measures regional tertiary education attainment shares labelled higher education workers. A second variable labelled lower education workers is proxied by the share of the working age population with lower secondary education levels or less.

We use data on patent numbers to proxy regional knowledge capital endowments. Patent data exhibit particularly desirable characteristics for this purpose, since they can be viewed as a direct result of research and development activities (LeSage and Fischer 2012). In order to construct regional knowledge stocks, we use the perpetual inventory method. We follow Fischer and LeSage (2015) and LeSage and Fischer (2012) to construct knowledge capital stocks \(K_{it}\) for region i in period t. Specifically, we define \(K_{it}=(1-r_K)K_{it-1}+P_{it}\), where \(r_K=0.10\) denotes a constant depreciation rate and \(P_{it}\) denotes the number of patent applications in region i at time t.

The matrix \(\varvec{D}\) includes several different distance metrics. First and foremost, we include the geodesic distance between parent and host regions. Recent empirical literature also consider common language as a potential quantity in \(\varvec{D}\) (see Krisztin and Fischer 2015, or Blonigen and Piger 2014). We measure whether the same official language is present in the source and host regions through a dummy variable. Information on official national and minority languages is obtained from the European Commission.

Several studies on FDI flows also highlight the importance of corporate tax rates as a potential key quantity to attract FDI inflows (see Blonigen and Piger 2014; Leibrecht and Riedl 2014; Bellak and Leibrecht 2009). Lower corporate income tax rates in the host region as compared to the origin region are thus expected to increase the potential attractiveness of FDI inflows. Matrix \(\varvec{D}\) therefore also contains the (country-specific) difference in corporate income tax rates between origin and destination regions. Larger differences are expected to be associated with increasing FDI inflows.

In order to alleviate potential endogeneity problems, we moreover measure all explanatory variables at the beginning of our sample (that is in 2003).Footnote 4 For specification of the spatial weight matrix, we rely on a row-stochastic seven nearest neighbour specification.Footnote 5 Data on the variables used stem from the fDi Markets, Cambridge Econometrics, as well as the Eurostat regional databases. Detailed information on the construction of the dependent and explanatory variables used are presented in Table 1.

Table 1 Variables used in the empirical illustration

4 Empirical results

This subsection presents the empirical results obtained from 15,000 posterior draws after discarding the first 10,000 as burn-ins. Running multiple chains with alternating starting values did not affect the empirical results, which also provides evidence for sampler convergence.

Posterior quantities for upstream-, downstream-, and production-related investment flows are presented in Tables 2, 3, and 4, respectively. Each table reports posterior means and posterior standard deviations for the quantities of interest. Statistical significance of the respective posterior mean estimates is based on a 90% credible interval and highlighted in bold. The first block in each table presents origin- and destination-specific slope parameter estimates, respectively. These estimates are reported for both own region characteristics as well as their spatial lags or third region characteristics (Baltagi et al. 2007). In the spatial econometrics literature, the former are often referred to as average direct impacts. Third region effects captured by spatially lagged counterparts are typically referred to as average indirect (or spillover) impacts (LeSage and Pace 2009). The second block in each table reports posterior summary metrics for the spatial autoregressive origin and destination random effects. The third and last block in each table shows posterior inference for the variables used in the distance matrix \(\varvec{D}\).

4.1 Origin- and destination-specific core variables

Table 2 reports posterior parameter estimates for upstream FDI (most notably consisting of business services and headquarters). Starting with the key drivers for regions producing FDI outflows in upstream-related activities, Table 2 shows particularly strong evidence for the importance of the own-regional market size and population density. In addition, the corresponding third-regional effects are significant and negative. For example, an increase in the market size restricted only to neighbouring regions thus decreases the amount of FDI outflows from a given region. The table also suggests a particularly accentuated importance of a well educated working age population (higher education workers) in the origin region. The estimated impact appears much more pronounced as compared to downstream and production FDI. Moreover, for upstream FDI the third region effect associated with the higher education workers variable also appears to be positive and highly significant. Own-regional knowledge capital endowments appear to be positively associated with the generation of upstream FDI outflows. However, the impacts of regional knowledge capital endowments for upstream FDI outflows appear rather muted as compared to the other types of FDI considered. Interestingly, Table 2 shows negative third-regional impacts for knowledge capital. Unlike other types of FDI under scrutiny, the compensation per hour variable only appears to have a significant impact for own-regional upstream FDI outflows.

Inspection of the regional determinants to attract upstream FDI inflows shows some interesting similarities to the origin-specific characteristics. This holds particularly true for the market size and population density variables. Both destination-specific variables show a positive and highly significant own-regional impact, with negative (and significant) spatial lags. Similar to the origin specific determinants of upstream FDI, the corresponding host-specific impacts appear more pronounced as in other activity types. This finding is in line with Henderson and Ono (2008), Defever (2006), or Duranton and Puga (2005), who highlight that the location choice of business services and headquarters related activities are particularly driven by functional aspects (rather than by sectoral aspects) and typically tend to be located in urban agglomerations. Regional FDI inflows associated with upstream investment activities moreover appear to be particularly attracted by regions with a higher specialization in the services sector (employment in services), relative to the agriculture sector (which serves as the benchmark in the specifications).

Table 2 Posterior parameter estimates for FDI associated with upstream value chains.

From a theoretical point of view, we would also expect labour costs, measured in terms of compensation per hours, to be an important determinant for attracting FDI inflows. This hypothesis is confirmed by inspecting the destination-specific results across all tables. Significant negative direct impacts of this variable can be observed throughout all stages of the value chain, both concerning the own region, as well as third regions. This corroborates the findings of Ascani et al. (2016b), who study the location determinants of Italian multinational enterprises. Regional knowledge capital as a pull-factor for upstream FDI inflows appears less relevant. Only the respective third-regional impact is significant, however, it appears comparatively muted.

Overall, the results for downstream FDI reported in Table 3 show a strong similarity to those of upstream FDI (Table 2). This resemblance can be observed for both origin- and destination-specific spatial determinants. For regions as a source of downstream FDI, Table 3 also highlights the key importance of agglomeration forces, proxied by the variables market size and population density. Both variables show a positive and significant direct impact for the generation of downstream FDI outflows, along with negative third-regional effects. These impacts, however, appear somewhat less pronounced as compared to upstream FDI. Similarly, the impact of regional tertiary education attainment (higher education workers) for downstream FDI outflows appears less accentuated as compared to upstream FDI outflows. As opposed to the results for origin-specific upstream FDIs, the third-regional effects of tertiary education attainment are insignificant. Regional knowledge capital endowments, on the other hand, appear somewhat more important for generating downstream FDI as compared to upstream FDI, with positive direct, and negative third-regional effects.

Table 3 Posterior parameter estimates for FDI associated with downstream value chains.

In line with the prevalent literature (see, among others, Leibrecht and Riedl 2014; Casi and Resmini 2010; or Baltagi et al. 2007), the destination-specific regional determinants for downstream FDI also show a strong importance of the market size and population density variables as a means to attracting downstream-related FDI inflows. Similar to destination-specific upstream FDI, educational attainment (lower and higher education workers) and the compensation per hour variable appear as important pull-factors. Concerning the regional industry mix, Table 3 suggests that higher shares in the industry and service sectors (employment in industry and services) appear to be significantly and positively associated with attracting downstream-related FDI inflows. An interesting result is given by a negative and statistically significant own-regional impact of the regional knowledge capital variable. The estimated impacts, however, appear rather offset by the positive third-regional impacts. Similar results can also be found in work by Dimitropoulou et al. (2013), a study on the location determinants of FDI for UK regions.

Empirical results for production-related FDI are summarized in Table 4. Starting with the origin-specific determinants of generating production FDI outflows, Table 4 shows not surprisingly a pronounced importance of regional market size and population density. Similar to the other types of FDI, both variables also exhibit significant negative third-regional effects. Interestingly, the source regional industry mix also appears to play a key role. Specifically, the employment in industry variable shows a positive and highly significant direct impact of the origin region. The remaining origin-specific drivers are basically in line with those of the other types of FDI, most notably positive impacts of tertiary education attainment (higher education workers) levels and regional knowledge capital endowments.

Table 4 Posterior parameter estimates for FDI associated with production value chains

Inspection of the destination-specific determinants of production-related FDI, however, reveals markedly different patterns as compared to upstream and downstream FDI. Albeit the market size shows a similar importance, along with negative third-regional effects, the direct impact of the population density variable shows a negative and significant sign. Our estimation results thus show that production-oriented FDI activities are predominantly attracted by smaller regions in proximity to urban agglomerations. For upstream and downstream activities, however, urban agglomerations seem to play a more central role. Moreover, our results imply that regional human capital endowments are particularly important for explaining upstream and downstream-oriented investment decisions. For production activities, the importance of regional human capital endowments appears slightly less pronounced. These results corroborate the findings of Strauss-Kahn and Vives (2009), and Defever (2006) by highlighting that industry-related location decisions typically focus on sectoral, rather than on functional aspects. The significant and positive own-regional, destination-specific industry mix (employment in industry and services) further underpins these findings.

For attracting production-related FDI, Table 4 shows a particularly pronounced negative impact of the compensation per hour variable of the host region. The negative direct impact on inflows is the strongest with a posterior mean of \(-1.21\) for production-related activities. However, it is worth noting that the associated third-regional impacts on inflows are insignificant for production, whereas both downstream and upstream related FDI flows exhibit significant negative third-regional impacts. Our findings are moreover in line with Fallon and Cook (2014) and Crescenzi et al. (2013), who both find that locational drivers for production-related FDI flows differ from those associated with business service activities.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Spatially structured origin- and destination-specific random effects across the value chain. Notes Regions that are not statistically significant under \(95\%\) credible intervals are shaded in white

4.2 Spatial-dependence and distance metrics

This subsection discusses the results for the spatial autoregressive origin and destination random effects, as well as the estimates of intervening opportunities from the distance matrix \(\varvec{D}\). Inspection of posterior estimates for the spatial latent random effects provides significant evidence for pronounced spatial dependence patterns in the random effects across all stages of the value chain. This finding holds true for both source- and host-regional heterogeneity in the sample. Posterior estimates for spatially structured origin- and destination-specific random effects for upstream, downstream and production stages of the value chain are illustrated in Fig. 1. Origin-specific effects are depicted in the top row, while destination-specific effects are in the bottom. Positive values are shaded in red, while negative values are shaded in blue. Regions which were not significant under a \(95\%\) posterior credible interval are shaded in white.

A comparison of their corresponding posterior means and standard deviations shows that all spatial autoregressive parameters are estimated with a high precision. The intensity of spatial dependence in the upstream- and downstream-specific latent unobservable effects appear similarly pronounced, with values ranging from 0.42 to 0.58. For production-related investment activities, the difference between \(\rho _o\) and \(\rho _d\) appears more pronounced, with the former being particularly sizeable (0.77), while the latter appears more muted.

Rather similar results for upstream, downstream and production are also reported for the distance factors collected in matrix \(\varvec{D}\). As expected, the posterior mean estimates for geographical distance are negative and significantly differ from zero for all types of investment activities. Moreover, the posterior standard deviations are comparatively small, indicating that the impact of geographic distance is estimated with a high precision. Higher geographic separation of two regions is thus associated with lower FDI activities, as increased distance often raises transportation, monitoring and thus investment costs. The negative impacts reported in Tables 2, 3, and 4 are in line with recent empirical results in FDI (Leibrecht and Riedl 2014) and trade literature (Krisztin and Fischer 2015).

Our dummy variable measuring whether a pair of regions shares an official common language proxies the cultural distance between regions in the sample. As expected, the reported posterior means show a positive sign and are significantly different from zero. The third distance variable in the matrix \(\varvec{D}\) measures the (country-specific) difference in corporate tax rates between source and target regions. In line with theoretical and empirical literature on the location choice of multinationals, the tables report significant and positive impacts to regional FDI flows when corporate tax rates in the target region are lower than in the source region (see Bellak and Leibrecht 2009 and Strauss-Kahn and Vives 2009). The estimated posterior means for the difference in tax rates suggest that a \(1\%\) decrease in the tax rate difference between source and destination regions results in a \(1.3\%\) and \(3.5\%\) increase in the number of FDI flows for downstream and upstream related activities, respectively.

5 Conclusions

This paper presents an empirical study on the spatial determinants of bilateral FDI flows among European regions. Due to data scarcity on the subnational level, previous papers typically adopt a national perspective when analysing FDI dyads (see, for example, Leibrecht and Riedl 2014). This paper thus provides a first spatial econometric analysis on the European regional level by explicitly accounting for origin-, destination-, and third region-specific factors in the analysis. The subnational perspective of our analysis allows us to study the spatial spillover mechanisms of regional FDI flows in more detail. Unlike recent studies on the locational determinants of FDI inflows (see, for example, Ascani et al. 2016b; or Crescenzi et al. 2013), we model FDI decision determinants not only across destination regions but also across the origin regional dimension. Moreover, due to the well-known need to control for spatial dependence when modelling regional data (LeSage and Pace 2009), we also capture spatial dependence through spatially structured random effects associated with origin and destination regions.

Our data comes from the fDi Markets database, which contains detailed information on regional FDI activities using media sources and company data. The data from the fDi Markets database also contains detailed sectoral information on the functional form of the FDI activity, which allows us to explicitly focus on FDI flows across different stages of the value chain. Specifically, the paper studies the origin- and destination-specific determinants of upstream, downstream, and production activities.

Our empirical results clearly indicate that both source and destination spatial dependence plays a key role for all investment activities under scrutiny. In line with recent literature, we find that regional market size, corporate tax rates, as well as third region effects appear to be of particular importance for all stages in the value chain. We moreover find that production-oriented FDI activities are predominantly attracted by smaller regions in proximity to urban agglomerations. For upstream and downstream activities, however, being in the same region as urban agglomerations seem to play a key role. Moreover, our results imply that regional human capital endowments are particularly important for explaining upstream and downstream-oriented investment decisions. For production activities, the importance of regional human capital endowments are less accentuated. These results corroborate the findings of Strauss-Kahn and Vives (2009), or Defever (2006) by highlighting that industry-related location decisions typically focus on sectoral, rather than on functional aspects. From an origin-specific perspective of FDI activities, our empirical results moreover clearly show that regional knowledge capital endowments appear crucial for host regions to produce FDI outflows. Similar to the results on the destination-specific factors for FDI inflows, we also find high education and agglomeration forces as particularly important aspects for host regional FDI outflows.