Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Growth and unemployment in an OLG economy with public pensions

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper develops an overlapping generations model including (1) a productive externality as an engine of endogenous growth and (2) wage setting by trade unions as the cause of unemployment. Within this framework, the paper considers growth and unemployment affected by public pensions under the following two types of pension system: the proportionate pension system where only the contributors, that is, the employed, receive pensions, and the lump-sum pension system where both the employed and the unemployed receive pensions. It is shown that public pensions create a trade-off between growth and employment in the former system, whereas they produce no trade-off in the latter.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to the OECD (2007), in some OECD countries, the redistributive part accounts for a larger share of pension benefits (for example, the Czech Republic, Luxembourg, and the UK); in other countries, the insurance part accounts for a larger share (for example, Hungary, Italy, Germany, Spain, and the USA).

  2. Undoubtedly, real pension systems are a mixture of these two systems. There are important institutional features of pensions missing from these two systems, and their absence makes the current approach only a crude approximation of reality. If some missing features are added to the current framework, then the refined model would make different predictions over a range of issues. Nevertheless, the initial and main intention of the current paper is not to compare various types of pension systems but to understand the major differences between the two pension systems analyzed by many previous studies. Our focus, therefore, is on a simper model that enables us to compare the two pension systems.

  3. The current analysis complements Cigno (2008). In a two-period life-cycle model without involuntary unemployment and capital accumulation, Cigno considered the following two pension systems: the Beveridgean system where pension benefits are unrelated to individual contributions and the Bismarckian system where pension benefits are related to individual contributions. He showed that the effects of pension policy on employment and efficiency differ between the two systems. The current paper differs from Cigno (2008) in that the paper includes involuntary unemployment and capital accumulation.

  4. The role of this assumption will be discussed in Section 5.

  5. In the real world, unemployment benefits rules are classified according to the following two dimensions: (1) lump sum vs proportional to wages and (2) taxable vs nontaxable (see, for example, Koskela and Schöb 1999, and the references therein). The choice of the rule may affect growth and unemployment (Daveri and Tabellini 2000; Chang et al. 2007). This paper follows Corneo and Marquardt (2000) and assumes the lump-sum, nontaxable unemployment benefits in order to compare the current paper’s result with that of Corneo and Marquardt (2000). The case of proportional or taxable benefits will be left for future research.

  6. Equation 4 indicates that, if η = 1, there is a possibility of \(s_{t}^{u}<0\). This implies that the unemployed want to borrow from the employed in the credit market in order to finance their consumption in youth. This paper assumes that such borrowing is available for the unemployed: that is, there is no limit of access to the credit market. Although a borrowing constraint may provide a richer set of outcomes and implications (for example, Renton 2002; Chetty 2005; Crossley and Low 2005; Sullivan 2005), this paper leaves it for future research and instead focuses attention on the interaction between public pensions, growth, and unemployment under the condition of no credit constraint.

  7. Devereux and Lockwood (1991), de la Croix and Licandro (1995), and Kaas and von Thadden (2003, 2004) consider Nash bargaining between unions and firms. The current framework can be viewed as a special case of their framework where unions have monopolistic power in negotiation.

  8. The second derivative of V t in Eq. 5 with respect to w t is given by:

    $$ \partial V_{t}^{2}/\partial w_{t}^{2}=\left\{ \frac{(1-\alpha )A_{t}}{1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}}\right\} ^{1/\alpha }K_{t}(w_{t})^{-(1/\alpha +1)}(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})\left( -1/\alpha +1\right) <0, $$

    which establishes the sufficiency of the first-order condition Eq. 6.

  9. When η = 0, the condition Eq. 6 is reduced to:

    $$ w_{t}=\frac{1}{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})}\left( u_{t}-\frac{ b_{\!t+1}}{R_{t+1}}\right) . $$

    Appendix C shows that u t  > b t + 1/R t + 1 holds; that is, the right-hand side of this equation is positive in equilibrium.

  10. A qualitatively identical result may hold in an economy with labor market fluctuations; see Layard and Nickell (1990), Layard et al. (1991), and Bräuninger (2005).

References

  • Adam A (2004) Macroeconomic effects of social security privatization in a small unionized economy. CESifo working paper no. 1371

  • Barr N, Diamond P (2006) The economics of pensions. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 22(1):15—39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ (1998) Revisiting European unemployment: unemployment, capital accumulation and factor prices. NBER Working Paper No. 6566

  • Bräuninger M (2005) Social security, unemployment, and growth. Int Tax Public Financ 12(4):423–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang J-J, Shaw M-F, Lai C-C (2007) A ‘Managerial’ trade union and economic growth. Eur Econ Rev 51(2):365–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty R (2005) Why do unemployment benefits raise unemployment durations? Moral hazard vs. liquidity. NBER Working Paper No. W11760. http://ssrn.com/abstract=847032

  • Cigno A (2008) Is there a social security tax wedge? Labour Econ 15(1):68–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coimbra R, Lloyd-Braga T, Modesto L (2005) Endogenous fluctuations in unionized economies with productive externalities. Econ Theory 26(3):629–649

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo G, Marquardt M (2000) Public pensions, unemployment insurance, and growth. J Public Econ 75(2):293–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crossley TF, Low HW (2005) Borrowing constraints, the cost of precautionary saving and unemployment insurance. Social and economic dimensions of an aging population research papers 125, McMaster University

  • Daveri F, Tabellini G (2000) Unemployment, growth and taxation in industrial countries. Econ Policy 15:47–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix D, Licandro O (1995) Underemployment, irreversiblilities, and growth under trade unionism. Scand J Econ 97(3):385–399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demmel R, Keuschnigg C (2000) Funded pensions and unemployment. FinanzArchiv 57(1):22–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devereux M, Lockwood B (1991) Trade unions, non-binding wage agreements, and capital accumulation. Eur Econ Rev 35(7):1411–1426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. Am Econ Rev 55(5):1126–1150

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreze JH, Modigliani F (1981) The trade-off between real wages and employment in an open economy. Eur Econ Rev 15(1):1–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farber HS (1978) Individual preferences and union wage determination: the case of the united mine workers. J Polit Econ 86(5):923–942

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Josten SD (2006) Dynamic fiscal policies and unemployment in a simple endogenous growth model. Int Tax Public Financ 13(6):701–716

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaas L, von Thadden L (2003) Unemployment, factor substitution and capital formation. Ger Econ Rev 4(4):475–495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaas L, von Thadden L (2004) Budgetary policy and unemployment dynamics in an OLG model with collective bargaining. Econ J 114(498):867–889

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koskela E, Schöb R (1999) Alleviating unemployment: the case for green tax reforms. Eur Econ Rev 43(9):1723–1746

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard R, Nickell S (1990) Is unemployment lower if unions bargain over employment? Q J Econ 105(3):773–787

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard R, Nickell S, Jackmann R (1991) Unemployment, macroeconomic performance and the labor market. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22(1):3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald IM, Solow RM (1981) Wage bargaining and employment. Am Econ Rev 71(5):896–908

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2007) Pensions at a glance 2007. OECD, Paris

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ono T (2007) Unemployment dynamics in an OLG economy with public pensions. Econ Theory 33(3):549–577

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oswald AJ (1982) The microeconomic theory of the trade union. Econ J 92(367):576–595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pencavel J (1984) The trade-off between wages and employment in trade union objectives. Q J Econ 99(2):215–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renton S (2002) Job search and asset accumulation under borrowing constraints. UPF economics and business working paper No. 649. http://ssrn.com/abstract=394421

  • Romer P (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94(5):1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan JX (2005) Borrowing during unemployment: unsecured debt as a safety net. In: Proceedings from Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, April Issue

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank two anonymous referees and the editor of this journal, Alessandro Cigno, for their valuable comments and suggestions. Financial support from the JSPS through a Grant-in-Aid for Young Scientists (B) (No. 20730208) is gratefully acknowledged. All remaining errors are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tetsuo Ono.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Appendix A: Derivation of Eqs. 10 and 11

From the savings functions Eqs. 3 and 4, the capital-market-clearing condition is:

$$ K_{t+1}=L_{t}\frac{w_{t}\big(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w}\big)-\phi (R)b_{\!t+1}}{1+\phi (R)R}+(N-L_{t})\frac{u_{t}-\phi (R)\eta b_{\!t+1}}{1+\phi (R)R}. $$

Multiplying both sides by 1 + ϕ(R)R, we have:

$$ \begin{array}{lll} (1+\phi (R)R)K_{t+1} &=&w_{t}L_{t}\big(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w}\big)+\big(N-L_{t}\big)u_{t} \\[4pt] &&-\,\big\{L_{t}+\big(N-L_{t}\big)\eta \big\}\phi (R)b_{\!t+1}\\[4pt] &=&\big\{\big(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w}\big)+\big(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f}\big)\big\}w_{t}L_{t} \\[4pt] &&-\,\phi (R)\big(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\big)w_{t+1}L_{t+1}\\[4pt] &=&\left\{\big(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w}\big)+\big(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f}\big)\right\}\frac{(1-\alpha )AK_{t}}{1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}}\\[4pt] &&-\,\phi (R)\big(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\big)\frac{ \big(1-\alpha \big)AK_{t+1}}{1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}}, \end{array} $$

where the equality in the second line is derived by using Eqs. 7 and 8 and the equality in the third line is derived by using Eq. 9. Rearranging the terms of the above equation, we obtain Eqs. 10 and 11.

1.2 Appendix B: Derivation of Eq. 12

The first-order condition for union wage setting Eq. 6 is rewritten as:

$$ \begin{array}{lll} (1-\alpha )(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})w_{t}L_{t} &=&u_{t}L_{t}+\frac{(-1+\eta )b_{\!t+1}L_{t}}{R} \\[5pt] &=&\frac{(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})w_{t}L_{t}}{N-L_{t}}L_{t}+\frac{(-1+\eta ) }{R}\\[5pt] &&\cdot \frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})w_{t+1}L_{t+1}}{L_{t}+(N-L_{t})\eta } L_{t} \\[5pt] &=&\frac{(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})w_{t}L_{t}}{N-L_{t}}L_{t}+\frac{(-1+\eta ) }{R}\\[5pt] &&\cdot \frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})Gw_{t}L_{t}}{L_{t}+(N-L_{t})\eta }L_{t}, \end{array} $$

where the equality in the second line is derived by using Eqs. 7 and 8 and the equality in the third line is derived by using w t + 1 L t + 1 = Gw t L t . Dividing both sides by w t L t and rearranging the terms, we obtain Eq. 12.

1.3 Appendix C: Proof of u t  > b t + 1/R (Footnote 9)

From Eqs. 7 and 8, u t  > b t + 1/R in the case of η = 0 is rewritten as:

$$ \frac{(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})w_{t}L_{t}}{N-L_{t}}>\frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})w_{t+1}L_{t+1}}{RL_{t}}=\frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})Gw_{t}L_{t}}{RL_{t}} . $$

Dividing both sides by w t N and rearranging the terms, we have:

$$ (\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})l>\frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G(1-l)}{R}. $$

We substitute the equilibrium employment rate Eq. 12 into the above inequality and rearrange the terms. Then, we find that u t  > b t + 1/R is rewritten as:

$$ (1-\alpha )(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})+\frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G}{R}>\frac{ (\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G}{R}. $$

This inequality holds for any set of parameters.

1.4 Appendix D: Proof of Proposition 4

In the case of η = 0, the employment rate is given by:

$$ l_{t}=\left[ \frac{\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f}}{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})+\frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G}{R}}+1\right] ^{-1}. \label{a1} $$
(17)
  1. 1.

    Given that \(\partial G/\partial \theta ^{w}=0\) (Proposition 1(1)), we immediately find that \(\left. \partial l\right\vert _{\eta =0}/\partial \theta ^{w}<0\) holds. In order to determine the sign of \(\left. \partial l\right\vert _{\eta =0}/\partial \theta ^{f}\), we focus on the first term within the square brackets, which is rewritten as:

    $$ \frac{\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f}}{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})+\frac{ (\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G}{R}}\!=\!\frac{1}{\underset{(a1)}{\underbrace{\frac{ (1-\alpha )(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})}{\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f}}}}+\underset{ (a2)}{\underbrace{\frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G}{R(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})}}} }. \label{a2} $$
    (18)

    The term (a1) is decreasing in θ f. The term (a2) is rewritten as:

    $$ (a2)=\frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})}{R}\times \frac{\frac{1}{1+\phi (R)R}\cdot \left\{ \frac{1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w}}{\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f}}+1\right\} (1-\alpha )A}{(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f})+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})(1-\alpha )A}, $$

    which shows that the term (a2) is decreasing in θ f. Thus, the left-hand side of Eq. 18 is increasing in θ f, which implies that \(\left. \partial l\right\vert _{\eta =0}/\partial \theta ^{f}<0\).

  2. 2.

    Equation 17 implies that the sign of \(\left. \partial l\right\vert _{\eta =0}/\partial \tau ^{f}\) is equivalent to the sign of \( \partial (\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G/\partial \tau ^{f}\). In order to determine the sign of \(\partial (\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G/\partial \tau ^{f}\), we rewrite (τ w + τ f)G as:

    $$ (\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G=\frac{\frac{1}{1+\phi (R)R}\cdot \left\{ (1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})+(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})\right\} (1-\alpha )A}{\frac{ 1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}}{\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}}+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R} (1-\alpha )A}. $$

    This equation implies \(\partial (\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G/\partial \tau ^{f}>0\) because \(\partial \{ (1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f})/(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})\} /\partial \tau ^{f}=\{\left( \tau ^{w}-(1+\theta ^{f})\right) \}/(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})^{2}<0\) holds.

  3. 3.

    Equation 17 implies that the sign of \(\left. \partial l\right\vert _{\eta =0}/\partial \tau ^{w}\) is equivalent to the sign of \( \partial \{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})+(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G/R\}/\partial \tau ^{w}.\) We derive the sufficient condition for \( \partial \{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})+(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G/R\}/\partial \tau ^{w}<0\).

The differentiation leads to:

$$\begin{array}{lll} &&\frac{\partial \left[ (1-\alpha )\left(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w}\right)+\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)G/R\right]}{\partial \tau ^{w}} \\ &&{\kern1pc} =-(1-\alpha )+\frac{G}{R}+\frac{\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)}{R}\times \frac{\partial G}{\partial \tau ^{w}}, \label{a4} \end{array} $$
(19)

where \(\partial G/\partial \tau ^{w}\) is given by:

$$ \frac{\partial G}{\partial \tau ^{w}}=(-1)G\frac{1+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}\cdot \frac{(1-\alpha )A}{1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}}\left(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}\right)}{(1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f})\left\{ 1+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)\frac{(1-\alpha )A}{1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}}\right\} }. \label{a4b} $$
(20)

Equations 19 and 20 imply that \(\left. \partial l\right\vert _{\eta =0}/\partial \tau ^{w}<0\) is equivalent to:

$$ \begin{array}{lll} &&\frac{1}{\alpha }\cdot \frac{1}{1+\phi (R)R}\left[ \left(1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f}\right)-\frac{1+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}(1-\alpha )A}{\frac{1}{\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}}+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}\cdot \frac{(1-\alpha )A}{1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}}}\right] \\ &&{\kern1pc} <(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f})+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)(1-\alpha )A. \label{a9} \end{array} $$
(21)

The left-hand side of Eq. 21, LHS, is decreasing in τ f whereas the right-hand side of Eq. 21, RHS, is increasing in τ f. Thus, Eq. 21 holds if \(\left. \text{LHS}\right\vert _{\tau ^{f}=0}<\left. \text{RHS}\right\vert _{\tau ^{f}=0},\) that is, if:

$$\begin{array}{lll} &&\frac{1}{\alpha }\cdot \frac{1}{1+\phi (R)R}\left[ (1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f})-\frac{1+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}(1-\alpha )A}{\frac{1}{\tau ^{w}}+ \frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}\cdot \frac{(1-\alpha )A}{1+\theta ^{f}}}\right] \\ &&{\kern1pc} <\left(1+\theta ^{f}\right)+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}\tau ^{w}(1-\alpha )A. \label{a10} \end{array} $$
(22)

Multiplying both sides of Eq. 22 by 1/τ w + {ϕ(R)/(1 + ϕ(R)R)}·{(1 − α)A/(1 + θ f)} and rearranging the terms, we obtain:

$$\begin{array}{lll} &&\left\{ \frac{1}{\tau ^{w}}+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}\cdot \frac{ (1-\alpha )A}{1+\theta ^{f}}\right\} \\ &&{\kern1pc} \times\left\{ \frac{1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f}}{ \alpha (1+\phi (R)R)}-\left(1+\theta ^{f}\right)-\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R}\tau ^{w}(1-\alpha )A\right\} \\ &&{\kern1pc} <\frac{1}{\alpha (1+\phi (R)R)}\left\{ 1+\frac{\phi (R)}{1+\phi (R)R} (1-\alpha )A\right\} . \label{a12} \end{array} $$
(23)

Thus, \(\left. \partial l\right\vert _{\eta =0}/\partial \tau ^{w}<0\) holds if Eq. 23 holds.

The remaining task is to derive the sufficient condition for which Eq. 23 holds. Because the right-hand side of Eq. 23 is positive, Eq. 23 holds if the left-hand side of Eq. 23 is nonpositive; that is, if:

$$ \frac{1+\theta ^{f}}{\alpha }\left\{1-\alpha (1+\phi (R)R)\right\}\leq \tau ^{w}\left[ \frac{1}{\alpha }+\phi (R)(1-\alpha )A\right] . \label{a13} $$
(24)

Condition (24) holds if:

$$ \left\{ \begin{array}{c} \alpha (1+\phi (R)R)\geq 1,\text{ or} \\ \alpha (1+\phi (R)R)<1\text{ and }\frac{(1+\theta ^{f})\left\{1-\alpha (1+\phi (R)R)\right\}}{1+\alpha \phi (R)(1-\alpha )A}\leq \tau ^{w}\text{.} \end{array} \right. \label{a14} $$
(25)

Thus, Eq. 25 is the sufficient condition for \(\left. \partial l\right\vert _{\eta =0}/\partial \tau ^{w}<0\).

1.5 Appendix E: Proof of Proposition 5

1.5.1 Derivation of the net replacement rate

Suppose that the net replacement rate is fixed at an exogenously given level for all t ≥ T. In the case of η = 1, the net replacement rate, \( x_{t}\equiv b_{\!t}/(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})w_{t},\) is rewritten as:

$$ x_{t}=\frac{\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)w_{t}}{\left(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w}\right)w_{t}}l_{t}= \frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})(1-\alpha )}{(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})+(1-\alpha )(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})}\equiv \bar{x}^{1}, \label{a15} $$
(26)

where the first equality is derived from the government budget constraint Eq. 7 and the second equality is derived from the equilibrium employment rate Eq. 12. Under the constraint of \(x_{t}=\bar{x}^{1}\) for all t ≥ T, Eq. 26 leads to the following marginal relationship between τ w and τ f:

$$ \frac{d\tau ^{f}}{d\tau ^{w}}=(-1)\left(1+\bar{x}^{1}\right). \label{a16} $$
(27)

In the case of η = 0, the government budget constraint Eq. 7 is rewritten as \(b_{\!t}=(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})w_{t}l_{t}/l_{t-1}\). We substitute this into the definition of the net replacement rate to obtain:

$$ x_{t}=\left\{ \begin{array}{c} \frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})l_{T}}{(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})l_{T-1}}\text{ if }t=T \\[8pt] \bar{x}^{0}\equiv \frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})}{(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})} \text{ if }t\geq T+1. \end{array} \right. \label{a18} $$
(28)

Note that l T  ≠ l T − 1 because l T − 1 is not affected by the changes in the contribution rates in period T. We hereafter focus on the net replacement rate in period t ≥ T + 1.

Under the constraint of \(x_{t}=\bar{x}^{0}\) for all t ≥ T + 1, Eq. 28 leads to the following marginal relationship between τ w and τ f:

$$ \frac{d\tau ^{f}}{d\tau ^{w}}=(-1)\left(1+\bar{x}^{0}\right). \label{a19} $$
(29)

1.5.2 Growth effect for the case of η = 1

The differentiation of G with respect to τ w leads to:

$$ \begin{array}{lll} \left. \frac{dG}{d\tau ^{w}}\right\vert _{x=\bar{x}} &=&\frac{(1-\alpha )A}{ \left\{ \left(1+\phi (R)R\right)\left(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}\right)+\phi (R)\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)(1-\alpha )A\right\} ^{2}} \\[6pt] &&\times \left[ (-1)\left\{ \left(1+\phi (R)R\right)\left(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}\right)+\phi (R)\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)(1-\alpha )A\right\} \right. \\[6pt] &&{\kern10pt} +\,(-1)\left(1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f}\right) \\[6pt] &&{\kern10pt} \times\left.\left\{ (1+\phi (R)R)d\tau ^{f}/d\tau ^{w} +\,\phi (R)\left( 1+d\tau ^{f}/d\tau ^{w}\right) (1-\alpha )A\right\} \right] . \end{array} $$

By using Eqs. 26 and 27, we can rewrite the above equation as follows:

$$\begin{array}{lll} \left. \frac{dG}{d\tau ^{w}}\right\vert _{x=\bar{x}} &=&\frac{(-1)(1-\alpha )A}{\left\{ \left(1+\phi (R)R\right)\left(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}\right)+\phi (R)\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)(1-\alpha )A\right\} ^{2}} \\[6pt] &&\times \left[ (1+\phi (R)R)\underset{(a3)}{\underbrace{\left\{ \left(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}\right)-\left(1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f}\right)\left(1+\bar{x}^{1}\right)\right\} }}\right. \\[3pt] &&\left. +\,\phi (R)(1-\alpha )A\underset{(a4)}{\underbrace{\left\{ \left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)-\left(1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f}\right)\bar{x}^{1}\right\} }}\right] . \label{a17} \end{array} $$
(30)

The terms (a3) and (a4) in Eq. 30 are rewritten as \( (a3)=(a4)=\alpha (\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})\bar{x}^{1}/(1-\alpha ).\) Therefore, Eq. 30 is reduced to:

$$ \left. \frac{dG}{d\tau ^{w}}\right\vert _{x=\bar{x}}\!=\!\frac{(-1)(1-\alpha )A\big\{(1+\phi (R)R)+\phi (R)(1-\alpha )A\big\}\frac{\alpha }{1-\alpha }\left(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f}\right)\bar{x}^{1}}{\left\{ \left(1+\phi (R)R\right)\left(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}\right)+\phi (R)\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)\left(1-\alpha \right)A\right\} ^{2}}\!<\!0. $$

1.5.3 Growth effect for the case of η = 0

Given the constraint Eq. 29, the differentiation of G with respect to τ w leads to:

$$ \begin{array}{lll} \left. \frac{dG}{d\tau ^{w}}\right\vert _{x=\bar{x}} &=&\frac{(-1)(1-\alpha )A}{\left\{ \left(1+\phi (R)R\right)\left(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}\right)+\phi (R)\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)\left(1-\alpha \right)A\right\} ^{2}} \\ &&\times \left[ \left(1+\phi (R)R\right)\underset{(a5)}{\underbrace{\left\{ \left(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}\right)-\left(1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f}\right)\left(1+\bar{x}^{0}\right)\right\} }}\right. \\ &&\left. +\,\phi (R)(1-\alpha )A\underset{(a6)}{\underbrace{\left\{ \left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)-\left(1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f}\right)\bar{x}^{0}\right\} }}\right] . \label{a25} \end{array} $$
(31)

By using Eq. 28, we can rewrite the terms (a5) and (a6) in Eq. 31 as \((a5)=(a6)=(-1)(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})\bar{x}^{0}\). Therefore, Eq. 30 is rewritten as:

$$ \left. \frac{dG}{d\tau ^{w}}\right\vert _{x=\bar{x}}=\frac{\left(1-\alpha\right )A\left(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f}\right)\bar{x}^{0}\big\{\left(1+\phi (R)R\right)+\phi (R)(1-\alpha )A\big\} }{\left\{ \left(1+\phi (R)R\right)\left(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f}\right)+\phi (R)\left(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f}\right)\left(1-\alpha \right)A\right\} ^{2}}>0. \label{a20} $$
(32)

1.6 Appendix F: Proof of Proposition 6

1.6.1 Employment effect for the case of η = 1

Equation 12 implies that \(\left. l\right\vert _{\eta =1}\) is decreasing in τ w and is independent of τ f. Thus, we obtain \(\left. \left. dl\right\vert _{\eta =1}/d\tau ^{w}\right\vert _{x=\bar{x}}<0\).

1.6.2 Employment effect for the case of η = 0

The equilibrium employment rate is given by:

$$ \begin{array}{lll} \left. l_{t}\right\vert _{\eta =0} &=&\left[ \frac{\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f}}{ (1-\alpha )(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})+\frac{(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})G}{R}}+1 \right] ^{-1} \\ &=&\left[ \frac{\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f}}{(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})\left\{ (1-\alpha )+\bar{x}^{0}G/R\right\} }+1\right] ^{-1}, \end{array} $$

where the second equality is derived by using Eq. 28. This equation implies that the sign of \(\left. \left. dl\right\vert _{\eta =0}/d\tau ^{w}\right\vert _{x=\bar{x}}<0\) is equivalent to the sign of \( d(1\!-\!\tau ^{w}\!-\!\theta ^{w})\big\{ (1\!-\!\alpha )\!+\!\bar{x}^{0}G/R\big\} /d\tau ^{w}\big\vert _{x=\bar{x}^{0}}\).

Given the constraint Eq. 29, the differentiation of \((1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})\left\{ (1-\alpha )+\bar{x}^{0}G/R\right\} \) with respect to τ w leads to:

$$ \begin{array}{lll} &&{\kern-6pt} \left. \frac{d(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})\left\{ (1-\alpha )+xG/R\right\} }{ d\tau ^{w}}\right\vert _{x=\bar{x}^{0}} \\ &&{\kern3pt} =(-1)\left\{ (1-\alpha )+\bar{x}^{0}\frac{G}{R}\right\} +(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})\frac{\bar{x}^{0}}{R} \\ &&{\kern16pt}\times \frac{(1-\alpha )A(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})\bar{x}^{0}\{(1+\phi (R)R)+\phi (R)(1-\alpha )A\}}{\left\{ (1+\phi (R)R)(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f})+\phi (R)(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})(1-\alpha )A\right\} ^{2}} \\ &&{\kern3pt} =(-1)(1-\alpha )-\bar{x}^{0}\frac{G}{R} \\ &&{\kern16pt} \times \left[ 1-\tfrac{(\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})\{(1+\phi (R)R)+\phi (R)(1-\alpha )A\}}{\left\{ (1+\phi (R)R)(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f})+\phi (R)(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})(1-\alpha )A\right\} (1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f})}\right] \\ &&{\kern3pt} =(-1)(1-\alpha )-\bar{x}^{0}\frac{G}{R} \\ &&{\kern16pt} \times \tfrac{\left\{ (\theta ^{w}+\theta ^{f})(1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f})+(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f})(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})\right\} (1+\phi (R)R)+(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})(1-\tau ^{w}-\theta ^{w})\phi (R)(1-\alpha )A\}}{ \left\{ (1+\phi (R)R)(1+\tau ^{f}+\theta ^{f})+\phi (R)(\tau ^{w}+\tau ^{f})(1-\alpha )A\right\} (1-\tau ^{w}+\theta ^{f})} \\ &&{\kern3pt} <0, \end{array} $$

where the first equality is derived by the substitution of Eq. 32 and the second equality is derived by using Eqs. 10 and 11.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ono, T. Growth and unemployment in an OLG economy with public pensions. J Popul Econ 23, 737–767 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-008-0225-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-008-0225-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation