Skip to main content

On Modeling the European Market for Natural Gas

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 2230 Accesses

Part of the book series: Energy Systems ((ENERGY))

Abstract

Several features may separately or in combination influence conduct and performance of an industry, e.g., the numbers of sellers or buyers, the degree of economies of scale in production and distribution, the temporal and spatial dimensions, uncertainty about long run development of demand in particular combined with large investments in production capacity and infrastructure, etc. Our focus is modeling in order to obtain insight into market mechanisms and price formation. In particular, we demonstrate the rather different solutions obtained from the price-taking behavior versus the oligopolistic Cournot behavior when the spatial dimension is observed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Smeers (1997) reviews models and issues in the European gas market.

  2. 2.

    Mathiesen et al. (1987) argue that shadow prices of the vast gas resources of the larger suppliers are close to zero whereby a static approach is appropriate from a resource perspective. The large profits in gas production are oligopolistic rents that stem from uneven distribution of the resources and not scarcity.

  3. 3.

    In order to reduce the risks caused by long lead times and large uncertainties, parties involved write long term contracts for deliveries. The terms of such contracts may not match price formation in an equilibrium model. But it seems that contracting clauses rather than being written in stone are modified when market conditions change, thereby adapting to the logic of the market mechanism.

  4. 4.

    Algeria, Russia, and The Netherlands each have only one (large) producer, while in Norway a central board coordinated sales for years.

  5. 5.

    For the analysis of investment in pipe capacities, modeling of flow as dependent on pressure at nodes may be important (see De Wolf and Smeers 1993).

  6. 6.

    The Statoil model is expanded, its database is updated, and the interactive program improved. It is helpful to analysts (see Fuglseth and Grønhaug 2003), but it may also be too complicated for most non-academics.

  7. 7.

    For a homogeneous product \(\partial p/\partial {x}_{1} = \partial p/\partial {x}_{2} = \ldots = \partial p/\partial {x}_{n} = p^{\prime}\).

  8. 8.

    Bowley (1924) introduced the idea. Game theorists dislike the concept – only the Nash solution θi = 0 is consistent. Others point out that θi≠0 in particular markets and that should be taken as a datum along with costs and demand. Bresnahan (1989) reviews several studies where such terms have been estimated.

  9. 9.

    A leader assumes that his followers adjust their volumes to satisfy their individual first order conditions. Their aggregate response follows from totally differentiating these conditions. The difference between the models stems from the different behavior of the followers – Cournot-players versus price-takers.

  10. 10.

    It is assumed that the cartel behaves as one Nash–Cournot player against non-members. Thus, θi = 0.

  11. 11.

    The acronym stands for A Sequence of Linear Complementarity Problems, describing a Newton-like iterative process where the linear conditions in each step are solved by Lemke’s method.

  12. 12.

    GAMS is a software package for a variety of optimization and equilibrium problems. It has become an industrial standard. See www.gams.com for details on content and how to obtain this package.

  13. 13.

    Samuelson (1952) originated this approach, demonstrating that in order to compute the competitive equilibrium one could maximize the sum of consumers’ and producers’ surpluses. See Takayama and Judge (1971) for applications.

  14. 14.

    Cf., integrability of demand in economic theory (see, e.g., Varian 1992).

  15. 15.

    With (p, Z) = (10, 40), price elasticity is − 1. When elasticities differ between regions ( − 0. 6 to − 1. 4), price differences in the Cournot equilibrium are still smaller.

  16. 16.

    A gas producer typically does not sell to final consumers, but to various agents who sell and distribute gas to final consumers. A model with successive market power would be more appropriate to capture price discrimination (cf., Boots et al. 2004 and Eldegard et al. 2001).

  17. 17.

    The Cournot equilibrium may have all nm flows positive, while the competitive equilibrium has at most (\(n + m - 1\)) positive flows. The latter fact is well known within operations research as a feature of a basicsolution to the transportation model and within trade theory through the notion of no cross-hauling.

  18. 18.

    It is interesting to note that a collusive outcome – where all producers coordinate their sales (see 2.3) – has the same efficient trade pattern as the competitive solution, although volumes are about 40% lower.

  19. 19.

    Of course, even though contracts involve sales from North to South and vice versa, transmission companies may avoid actual cross-hauling.

  20. 20.

    In reality, fixed costs of deliveries block small flows. In modeling terms, this feature implies non-convexities that are hard, but not impossible, to implement in an optimization or equilibrium model.

  21. 21.

    In line with the regional disaggregation of this example, the European natural gas market has at present about 20 positive flows. When asked why Statoil would sell to Italy rather than Germany, a sales representative commented: “We already sell much in Germany and selling larger volumes would depress our prices there.”

  22. 22.

    Of course, deliveries from any supplier could be constrained in the competitive model in order to prevent such dominance.

  23. 23.

    Traded volumes in the competitive equilibrium depend on transportation cost in a step-like manner, that is, a volume stays fixed for cost variations over some range and then jumps. The difference in net-back prices between a market that is served and one that is not served may be arbitrarily small. In our example, N does not serve market 3 until transportation cost is below 1.99. But at a unit cost of 1.98 A shifts his entire volume (17) from market 1 to market 3 and B shifts a similar volume oppositely. Who sells where in a competitive equilibrium is therefore very sensitive to relative transportation costs. Individual flows in the Cournot equilibrium are much more stable to such parameter changes. (Aggregate flows of production and consumption, however, are very stable in both models.)

  24. 24.

    When establishing a gas model for the European market in the mid-1980s it seemed that actual gas-prices were reduced going east to west in Europe. The reason could be that USSR met no competition in eastern markets, while there were alternative suppliers and hence competition in the West.

  25. 25.

    The MCP-solver of GAMS replicated the Nash equilibrium when the mark-up was computed immediately following the computation of the (true) Nash, but it generated a trade pattern with 9 flows when the mark-up equilibrium was computed immediately following the competitive one (or when the matrix of λij’s was input to a new run). Although both these trade patterns had 9 positive flows only two flows were positive in both equilibria. The reason for these seemingly arbitrary trade patterns in the mark-up equilibrium stems from the definition of λij whereby reduced costs \(\{{p}_{\mathrm{j}} - ({c}_{\mathrm{i}} + {t}_{\mathrm{ij}})(1 + {\lambda }_{\mathrm{ij}})\} = 0\), all i, j, at the equilibrium admitting any trade pattern that adds up to equilibrium production and consumption volumes.

References

  • Beltramo, M. A., Manne, A. S., & Weyant, J. P. (1986). A North American gas trade model (GTM). The Energy Journal, 7(5), 15–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Berg, M. (1990). Økt tilbud av naturgass fra Canada til USA: En markedsstrategisk analyse. (Increased supply of natural gas from Canada to the United States: A strategic market analysis). Working paper 16/90. Bergen: Senter for Anvendt Forskning (Center for Applied Research)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjerkholt, O., Gjelsvik, E., & Olsen, Ø. (1989). Gas trade and demand in Northwest Europe: Regulation, bargaining and competition. Discussion Paper 45/89. Oslo: Statistics Norway

    Google Scholar 

  • Boots, M. G., Rijkers, F. A. M., & Hobbs, B. F. (2004). Trading in the downstream European gas market: A successive oligopoly approach. The Energy Journal, 25(5), 73–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Boucher, J., & Smeers, Y. (1984). Simulation of the European gas market up to the year 2000. Discussion paper 8448. Louvain-la-Neuve: CORE

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowley, A. L. (1924). The mathematical groundwork of economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Brekke, K. A., Gjelsvik, E., & Vatne, B. H. (1987). A dynamic supply side game applied to the European gas market. Discussion paper 22/87. Oslo: Statistics Norway

    Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan, T. F. (1989). Studies of industries with market power. In R. Schmalensee & R. D. Willig (Eds.), The handbook of industrial organization. Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company

    Google Scholar 

  • De Wolf, D., & Smeers, Y. (1993). Optimal dimensioning of pipe networks with an application to gas transmission networks. Discussion paper 9315. Louvain-la-Neuve: CORE

    Google Scholar 

  • Eldegard, T., Mathiesen, L., & Skaar, J. (2001). A partial equilibrium model of the European natural gas market. SNF Report 52/01. Bergen: Stiftelsen for samfunns- og næringslivsforskning (Institute for Research in Economics and Business Administration)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuglseth, A. M., & Grønhaug, K. (2003). Can computerised market models improve strategic decision-making? An exploratory study. Journal of Socio-Economics, 32(5), 503–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golombek, R., Gjelsvik, E., & Rosendahl, K. E. (1995). Effects of liberalizing the natural gas markets in Western Europe. The Energy Journal, 16(1), 85–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golombek, R., Gjelsvik, E., & Rosendahl, K. E. (1998). Increased competition on the supply side of the Western European natural gas market. The Energy Journal, 19(3), 1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grais, W., & Zheng, K. (1996). Strategic interdependence in European East–West gas trade: A hierarchical Stackelberg game approach. The Energy Journal, 17(3), 61–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoel, M. et al. (1987). The market for natural gas in Europe: The core of a game. Memo 13. Oslo: Department of Economics, University of Oslo

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller, L. (2001). BP. Presentation at NPF Trondheim. May 28, 2001

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathiesen, L. (1985). Computational experience in solving equilibrium models by a sequence of linear complementarity problems. Operations Research, 33, 1225–1250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathiesen, L. (1987). GAS: En modell og et interaktivt system for analyser av det vest-europeiske marked for naturgass (A model and an interactive system for analysis of the Western European market for natural gas). Report 3. Bergen: Senter for Anvendt Forskning (Center for Applied Research)

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathiesen, L. (1988). Analyzing the European market for natural gas. Working paper 37/88. Bergen: Senter for Anvendt Forskning (Center for Applied Research)

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathiesen, L., Roland, K., & Thonstad, K. (1987). The European natural gas market: Degrees of market power on the selling side. In R. Golombek, M. Hoel, J. Vislie (Eds.), Natural gas markets and contracts. Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1952). Spatial price equilibrium and linear programming. American Economic Review, 32(4), 510–524

    Google Scholar 

  • Slade, M. (1994). What does an oligopoly maximize? Journal of Industrial Economics, 57(2), 45–62

    Google Scholar 

  • Smeers, Y. (1997). Computable equilibrium models and the restructuring of the European electricity and gas markets. The Energy Journal, 18(4), 1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takayama, T., & Judge, G. G. (1971). Spatial and temporal price allocation models. Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company

    Google Scholar 

  • Tandberg, E. (1990). Naturgass i det nordiske energimarkedet (Natural gas in the Nordic energy market). Rapport 4/90. Bergen: Senter for Anvendt Forskning (Center for applied research)

    Google Scholar 

  • Tandberg, E. (1992). Introduction of natural gas in the Scandinavian energy market. HAS-thesis NHH and working paper 53/92. Bergen: Stiftelsen for samfunns- og næringslivsforskning (Institute for Research in Economics and Business Administration)

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. (1992). Microeconomic analysis. New York: Norton and Co

    Google Scholar 

  • von Hirschhausen, C., Meinhart, B., & Pavel, F. (2005). Transporting Russian gas to Western Europe: A simulation analysis. The Energy Journal, 26(2), 49–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Øygard, S. H., & Tryggestad, J. C. (2001). Volatile gas. McKinsey Quarterly, 3

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper summarizes my experience of gas market modeling. Very helpful comments from two referees are acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lars Mathiesen .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Mathiesen, L. (2010). On Modeling the European Market for Natural Gas. In: Bjørndal, E., Bjørndal, M., Pardalos, P., Rönnqvist, M. (eds) Energy, Natural Resources and Environmental Economics. Energy Systems. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-12067-1_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-12067-1_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-12066-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-12067-1

  • eBook Packages: EngineeringEngineering (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics