Skip to main content

Linkages Between Formal Institutions, ICT Adoption, and Inclusive Human Development in Sub-Saharan Africa

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Catalyzing Development through ICT Adoption

Abstract

This study empirically assesses the effects of formal institutions on ICT adoption in 49 African countries over the years 2000–2012. It deploys 2SLS and FE regression models (a) to estimate the determinants of ICT adoption and (b) to trace how ICT adoption affects inclusive development. The results show that formal institutions affect ICT adoption in this group of countries, with government effectiveness having the largest positive effects and regulations the largest negative effects. However, while formal institutions generally affect ICT adoption positively, population and economic growth tend to constrain ICT adoption more in low-income countries than middle-income countries. The results further demonstrate that the effects of ICT adoption on development are comparable to those of domestic credit and foreign direct investment. Ceteris paribus, one may conclude that external factors like foreign aid are more limiting to inclusive development than internal factors. This suggests that developing countries, African countries in this specific case, can enhance their ICT adoption for development by improving formal institutions and by strengthening domestic determinants of ICT adoption. Both represent opportunities for further research.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    Wherever the term “adoption” appears in this study, it should be read and understood as “adoption with diffusion.” Under conditions of rapid technological change, an ICT that is just adopted may never be diffused, and for this reason we stress ICTs that have been adopted and penetrating the economy as catalysts for inclusive development.

  2. 2.

    The World Bank data is available at: http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.aspx#home.

  3. 3.

    Note that the existence of entrepreneurs with access to private credit is a key driver of capital formation in a Schumpeterian model – Eq. (10.2) above.

  4. 4.

    For a description of how the Polity 2 index is calculated, we refer the interested reader to [14]), p. 39ff.

  5. 5.

    We refer the interested reader to Willian J. Baumol’s The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism. Princeton/Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2002. However, this great work was not fundamental to our work and therefore we do not include it in our list of cited work.

References

  1. Norris, P. (2001). Digital divide?: Civic engagement, information poverty and the internet worldwide. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  2. Steinmueller, W. (2001). ICTs and the possibilities of leapfrogging by developing countries. International Labour Review, 140(2), 193–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. (2003). Computing productivity: Firm-level evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(4), 793–808.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Wallsten, S. (2005). Regulation and internet use in developing countries. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 53(2), 501–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Harggitai, E. (1999). Weaving the western web: Explaining differences in internet connectivity among OECD countries. Telecommunications Policy, 23(10–11), 701–718.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Quibria, M., Ahmed, S., Tschang, T., & Reyes-Macasaquit, M. (2003). Digital divide: Determinants and policies with special reference to Asia. Journal of Asian Economics, 13(6), 811–825.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Dasgupta, S., Lall, S., & Wheeler, D. (2005). Policy reform, economic growth and the digital divide. Oxford Development Studies, 33(2), 229–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Oxley, J., & Yeung, B. (2001). E-commerce and readiness institutional environment and international competitiveness. Journal of International Business Studies, 32(4), 705–723.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Robison, K., & Crenshaw, E. (2002). Post-industrial transformations and cyber-space: A cross national analysis of internet development. Social Science Research, 31(3), 334–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Kiiski, S., & Pohjola, M. (2002). Cross-country diffusion of the internet. Information Economics and Policy, 14(2), 297–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Bellock, R., & Dimitrova, D. (2003). An explanatory model of inter-country internet diffusion. Telecommunications Policy, 27(3–4), 237–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Chinn, M., & Fairlie, R. (2007). The determinants of the global digital divide: A cross country analysis of computer and internet penetration. Oxford Economic Papers, 59(1), 16–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Billón, M., Marco, R., & Lera-Lopez, F. (2009). Disparities in ICT adoption: A multidimensional approach to study the cross-country digital divide. Telecommunications Policy, 33, 596–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Kiessling, J. (2007). Institutions and ICT technology adoption. Department of Economics. Sweden: Stockholm University.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Dekimpe, M. K., Parker, P. M., & Sarvary, M. (2000). Globalization: Modeling technology adoption timing across countries. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 63, 125–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Amavilah, V.H. (2008). Inhibited (exhibited) spread of innovations. MPRA paper 8993, University Library Munich.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Amavilah, V. H. S. (2007). Innovations spread more like wildfire than like infections. Social Science Research Network (SSRN) Working paper No. 99950.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Wejnert, B. (2002). Integrating models of diffusion of innovations: A conceptual framework. Annual Reviews of Sociology, 28, 297–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Young, H. P. (2006a). Innovation diffusion and population heterogeneity. Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Young, H. P. (2006b). The spread of innovations by social learning, Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Young, H. P. (2009). Innovation diffusions in heterogeneous populations: Contagion, social influence, and social learning. American Economic Review, 99(5), 1829–1944.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Geroski, P. A. (2000). Models of technology diffusion. Research Policy, 29(4/5), 603–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Rogers, E. M. (1995). Diffusion of innovations. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Caselli, F., & Coleman II, W. (2001). Cross-country technology diffusion: The case of computers. American Economic Review, 91(2), 328–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Baliamoune-Lutz, M. (2003). An analysis of the determinants and effects of ICT diffusion in developing countries. Information Technology for Development, 10(2), 151–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Detschew, S. (2007). Impact of ICT in the developing countries on the economic growth: Implications derived from theory and empiricism. DiplomaThesis, Technical University of Ilmenau, Germany.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Papaioannou, S. K., & Dimelis, S. P. (2007). Information technology as a factor of economic development: Evidence from developed and developing countries. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 16(3), 179–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Gholami, R., Higón, D. A., Hanafizedh, P., & Emrouznejad, A. (2010). Is ICT the key to development? Journal of Global Information Management, 18(1), 66–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Seo, H. J., Lee, Y. S., & Oh, J. H. (2009). Does ICT investment widen the growth gap? Telecommunications Policy, 3, 422–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Tchamyou, V. S.. (2015). The role of knowledge economy in African business, African Governance and Development Institute Working Paper No. 15/049, Yaoundé.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2010). The worldwide governance indicators: Methodology and analytical issues. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper no. 5430.

    Google Scholar 

  32. UNCTAD. (2006). Using ICTs to achieve growth and development. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development TD/B/COM.3/EM.29/2.

    Google Scholar 

  33. UNCTAD (2011). Measuring the impacts of information and communication technology for development. United Nations Conference for Trade and Development.

    Google Scholar 

  34. UNDP (2008). The role of information communication technologies in achieving the millennium development goals. United Nations Development Programme Mozambique.

    Google Scholar 

  35. UNDP (2010). ICT4D and the human development and capability approach: The potentials of information communication technologies. United Nations Development Programme.

    Google Scholar 

  36. World Bank (2009). Information communications technologies for development. http://live.worldbank.org/information-communications-technology-development.

  37. World Bank (2012). ICT for greater development impact 2012–2015.World Bank Group Strategy: Information & Communication Technology.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Binder, M., & Georgiadis, G. (2011). Determinants of human development: Capturing the role of institutions. CESIFO Working Paper No. 3397.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Rodrik, D. (2000). Institutions for high-quality growth: What they are, how to acquire them. NBER Working Paper No. W7540.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Rodrik, D. (2001). The global governance of trade as if development really mattered. Report submitted to United Nations Development Programme (UNDP).

    Google Scholar 

  41. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2008). The role of institutions in growth and development. In D. Brady & M. Spence (Eds.), Leadership and growth. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(2), 131–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Anand, R., Mishra, S., & Spatafora, N. (2012). Structural transformation and the sophistication of production, IMF Working Paper No. 12/59, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Mlachila, M., Tapsoba, R., & Tapsoba, S. J. A. (2014). A quality of growth index for developing countries: A proposal. IMF Working Paper No. 14/172, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Asongu, S. A., & Nwachukwu, J. C. (2016a). Mobile phones in the diffusion of knowledge and persistence in inclusive human development in sub-Saharan Africa. Information Development, 32(3), 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Hamdan Livramento, I. M., & Foray, D. (2007). Does IPR protection affect high growth entrepreneurship? A cross-country empirical examination. European Policy for Intellectual Property, 2nd Annual Conference of the EPIP Association, Sweden.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Asongu, S. A. (2013). How would population growth affect investment in the future? Asymmetric panel causality evidence for Africa. African Development Review, 25(1), 14–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Fosu, A. K. (2015). Growth, inequality and poverty in sub-Saharan Africa: Recent progress in a global context. Oxford Development Studies, 43(1), 44–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Asongu, S. A., & Nwachukwu, J. C. (2016b). The mobile phone in the diffusion of knowledge for institutional quality in sub-Saharan Africa. World Development, 86, 133–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Asongu, S. A. (2014). The questionable Economics of development assistance in Africa: Hot-fresh evidence, 1996–2010. The Review of Black Political Economy, 41(4), 455–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  52. Asongu, S. A., & Nwachukwu, J. C. (2016c). The role of governance in mobile phones for inclusive human development in sub-Saharan Africa. Technovation, 55–56, 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Schumpeter, J. A. (2005). Development. Journal of Economic Literature, XLIII(1), 108–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  54. Becker, M. C., Eblinger, H. U., Hedtke, U., & Knudsen, T. (2005). Introduction to development by Joseph A. Schumpeter. Journal of Economic Literature, XLIII(1), 110–111.

    Google Scholar 

  55. Bazhal, I. (2016). The theory of economic development of J.A. Schumpeter: Key features. MPRA Paper 69883, University Library of Munich, Germany, revised 25 Feb.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the editor and one anonymous reviewer for constructive comments on earlier drafts of the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Antonio Rodrìguez Andrés .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Supplementary Material for the Editor

Supplementary Material for the Editor

1.1 Supplement 1: The Theory Behind the Model

We assume a basic Schumpeterian model in which the economic activity is described as:

$$ {Y}_i=\left({A}_i^{\alpha_i}{S}_i^{\beta_i\ }{X}_i^{\gamma_i}\right) \exp \left({\mu}_i\right) $$
(10.3)

where, Y i is the real GDP of the ith economy, in Schumpeter’s terminology A i (technology, including ICT) and S i (socioeconomic setting, including institutions) are “evolution components”, X i are “growth components”, including conventional factors of production, and all variables are dated ([53]; cf. [54, 55]). Central to growth among X i is capital accumulation, which over time depends on investment (I) equal to savings in a steady state. Savings come from profit (π) made possible by technological change and the socioeconomic setting surrounding it. The evolution of the socioeconomic environment is a function of resources, technology, and level of development, i.e.:

$$ \frac{d{ K}_{i t}}{ d t}= k\left[\frac{d{ I}_{i t}}{ d t}= f\left({\pi}_i\ \left({A}_i,{S}_i\right)\right)\right],\frac{d{ S}_{i t}}{ d t}= s\left({X}_i,,{A}_i,,{S}_i\right),\pi =\mathrm{profit}. $$
(10.4)

A Schumpeterian technological change is discontinuous due to five initiators: (a) introduction of new ideas, requiring technological know-how; (b) introduction of new production techniques for which funds (credit) are essential; (c) discovery of new sources of supply; (d) discovery of new markets; and (e) change in the structure and organization of the industry involved. Thus, in dynamic form Eq. (10.1) is characterized by the Schumpeter-Kondratiev waves (cycles), such that A i over time is sinusoid, i.e.:

$$ {A}_i(t)={A}_0 \exp \left(\varphi t+ \cos \left( bt+\psi \right)\right) $$

and \( \partial A/\partial t={A}_0\left(\varphi - b\right) \sin\ \left( bt+\psi \right) \exp\ \left(\varphi t+ \cos\ \left( bt+\psi \right)\right), \) which is consistent with [15] Eqs. (10.3 and 10.4 (p. 6)), but we do not pursue this line of thought further. Instead, from Eq. (10.1) we solve for A i as:

$$ {A}_i={Y}_i^{1/{\alpha}_i}{S}_i^{-{\beta}_i/{\alpha}_i}{X}_i^{-{\gamma}_{i/{\alpha}_i}}. $$
(10.5)

Dividing both sides of Eq. (10.3) Equation 10.5 by some specific \( {X}_i={X}_i^{\ast } \) such as population or labor (worker), and taking the natural logs on both sides, we get a per capita (per labor, per worker, per head) indicator of adoption with diffusion as follows:

$$ {\dot{\mathrm{A}}}_i={\alpha}_i^{\ast }{y}_i+{\beta}_i^{\ast }{\dot{s}}_i+{\gamma}_i^{\ast }{\dot{x}}_i+{\mu}_i $$
(10.6)

where \( \begin{array}{l}\dot{\mathrm{A}}= \log \left(\frac{A_i}{X_i^{\ast }}\right)= IC{T}_i;{\alpha}_i^{\ast }=\frac{1}{\alpha};{\dot{y}}_i=\mathrm{economic}\;\mathrm{growth};\hfill \\ {}{\beta}_i^{\ast }=\frac{\beta_i}{\alpha_i};{\dot{s}}_i= \log \left(\frac{S_i}{X_i^{\ast }}\right)=\mathrm{economic}\;\mathrm{setting}\ \left(\mathrm{governance}\right);\hfill \\ {}{\gamma}_i^{\ast }=\frac{\gamma_i}{\alpha_i};{\dot{x}}_i=\frac{X_i}{X_i^{\ast }}=\mathrm{primary}\kern0.75em and\kern0.75em \mathrm{other}\kern0.75em \mathrm{drivers};\kern0.5em \hfill \\ {} and\kern0.5em {\mu}_i=\mathrm{the}\kern0.5em \mathrm{random}\kern0.5em \mathrm{classical}\kern0.5em \mathrm{error}\kern0.5em \mathrm{term}.\hfill \end{array} \)

This all shows that in the main document, the ICT equation is the equivalent of 10.(6) Eq. (10.4) above, and the development equation is Eq. (10.1) 10.3.

1.2 Supplement 2: A Note on Country Classification by Income Level

The World Bank classifies countries as developing if they are low income ($0–1,045 per capita) and lower middle income ($1,046–4,125 per capita). Countries with upper middle incomes ($4,126–12, 735 per capita) and high incomes ($12,736 or higher) are classified as being developed. The classification is arbitrary. No particular line of reasoning is given for why the cutoff point between “developed” and “developing” is set at $12,735. There is no reason to believe that a country just below the cutoff line cannot be more “developed” than a country just above it. For instance, Equatorial Guinea has a higher average income level than both China and South Africa, but its industrial base and technological structure are miles far behind. This is one of the reasons we modified the World Bank and grouped African countries into two groups: low-income group consisting of 28 countries, and middle-income group made up of 21 countries. This reclassification is consistent with our understanding of both ICT and development in these countries.

1.3 Supplement 3: ICT Variable Definitions and Data Sources

Variables

Signs

Definitions

Sources

Mobile phone

Mobile

Mobile phone subscriptions (per 100 people)

WDI

Internet

Internet

Internet subscriptions (per 100 people)

WDI

Telephone

Telephone

Telephone subscriptions (per 100 people)

WDI

Political stability

PolS

“Political stability/no violence (estimate): measured as the perceptions of the likelihood that the government will be destabilized or overthrown by unconstitutional and violent means, including domestic violence and terrorism”

WGI

Voice and accountability

VA

“Voice and accountability (estimate): measures the extent to which a country’s citizens are able to participate in selecting their government and to enjoy freedom of expression, freedom of association, and a free media”

WGI

Government effectiveness

GE

“Government effectiveness (estimate): measures the quality of public services, the quality and degree of independence from political pressures of the civil service, the quality of policy formulation and implementation, and the credibility of governments’ commitments to such policies”

WGI

Regulation quality

RQ

“Regulation quality (estimate): measured as the ability of the government to formulate and implement sound policies and regulations that permit and promote private sector development”

WGI

Corruption control

CC

“Control of corruption (estimate): captures perceptions of the extent to which public power is exercised for private gain, including both petty and grand forms of corruption, as well as ‘capture’ of the state by elites and private interests”

WGI

Rule of law

RL

“Rule of law (estimate): captures perceptions of the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide by the rules of society and in particular the quality of contract enforcement, property rights, the police, the courts, as well as the likelihood of crime and violence”

WGI

GDP growth

GDPg

GDP growth rate

WDI

Trade openness

Trade

Import plus exports of goods and services (% of GDP)

WDI

Population growth

Population

Total population growth (annual %)

WDI

Education

PSE

Primary school enrolment (% of gross)

WDI

  1. WGI World Governance Indicators, WDI World Development Indicators, GDP gross domestic product

1.4 Supplement 4: ICT Summary Statistics

 

Mean

SD

Min

Max

Obs

Mobile phone penetration

23.379

28.004

0.000

147.202

572

Internet penetration

4.152

6.450

0.005

43.605

566

Telephone penetration

3.039

5.810

0.005

32.455

565

Political stability

−0.543

0.956

−3.323

1.192

578

Voice and accountability

−0.646

0.737

−2.233

0.990

578

Government effectiveness

−0.771

0.620

−2.450

0.934

577

Regulation quality

−0.715

0.644

−2.665

0.983

578

Corruption control

−0.642

0.591

−1.924

1.249

579

Rule of law

−0.741

0.662

−2.668

1.056

578

GDP growth

4.714

6.322

−47.552

63.379

608

Trade openness

78.177

36.138

20.964

209.874

597

Population growth

2.361

0.948

−1.081

6.576

588

Education

97.446

25.895

32.199

181.700

470

  1. SD standard deviation, Min minimum, Max maximum, Obs observations, Adj adjusted

1.5 Supplement 5: ICT Correlation Matrix (Uniform Sample Size: 407)

Governance variables

Control variables

Dependent variables

PolS

VA

GE

RQ

CC

RL

GDPg

Trade

Popg

PSE

Mobile

Internet

Telephone

 

1.000

0.636

0.605

0.538

0.614

0.767

−0.084

0.253

−0.271

0.255

0.298

0.312

0.470

PolS

 

1.000

0.740

0.727

0.612

0.787

0.018

0.014

−0.250

0.248

0.274

0.325

0.459

VA

  

1.000

0.845

0.979

0.874

0.030

0.021

−0.335

0.212

0.293

0.320

0.504

GE

   

1.000

0.649

0.772

−0.025

−0.002

−0.247

0.217

0.264

0.176

0.286

RQ

    

1.000

0.817

−0.090

−0.014

−0.309

0.118

0.273

0.342

0.565

CC

     

1.000

−0.044

0.109

−0.286

0.219

0.274

0.332

0.530

RL

      

1.000

0.029

0.157

0.083

−0.043

−0.002

−0.052

GDPg

       

1.000

−0.380

0.167

0.259

0.158

0.228

Trade

        

1.000

−0.172

−0.331

−0.414

−0.581

Popg

         

1.000

0.288

0.224

0.181

PSE

          

1.000

0.690

0.479

Mobile

           

1.000

0.695

Internet

            

1.000

Telephone

  1. PolS Political stability, VA voice and accountability, GE government effectiveness, RQ regulation quality, CC corruption control, RL rule of law, GDPg GDP per capita growth rate, Popg population growth, PSE primary school enrolment, Mobile mobile phone penetration, Internet Internet penetration, Telephone telephone penetration

1.6 Supplement 6: IHDI Variable Definitions and Data Sources

Variables

Signs

Definitions

Sources

Inclusive development

IHDI

Inequality-adjusted human development index

UNDP

Mobile phone

Mobile

Mobile phone subscriptions (per 100 people)

WDI

Internet

Internet

Internet subscriptions (per 100 people)

WDI

Telephone

Telephone

Telephone subscriptions (per 100 people)

WDI

Foreign aid

Aid

Total official development assistance (% of GDP)

WDI

Private credit

Credit

Private credit by deposit banks and other financial institutions (% of GDP)

WDI

Remittance

Remit

Remittance inflows (% of GDP)

WDI

Foreign investment

FDI

Foreign direct investment net inflows (% of GDP)

WDI

  1. UNDP United Nations Development Program, WDI World Development Indicators, GDP gross domestic product

1.7 Supplement 7: IHDI Summary Statistics

 

Mean

SD

Min

Max

Obs

Inequality-adjusted human development

0.721

3.505

0.129

0.768

485

Mobile phone penetration

23.379

28.004

0.000

147.202

572

Internet penetration

4.152

6.450

0.005

43.605

566

Telephone penetration

3.039

5.810

0.005

32.455

565

Foreign aid

11.687

14.193

−0.253

181.187

606

Private domestic credit

18.551

22.472

0.550

149.78

507

Remittances

3.977

8.031

0.000

64.100

434

Net foreign direct investment inflows

5.332

8.737

−6.043

91.007

603

  1. SD standard deviation, Min minimum, Max maximum, Obs observations, Adj adjusted

1.8 Supplement 8: IHDI Correlation Matrix (Uniform Sample Size: 324)

Foreign aid

Credit

Remittances

FDI

Mobile

Internet

Telephone

IHDI

 

1.000

−0.173

−0.037

0.411

−0.165

−0.196

−0.223

−0.382

Foreign aid

 

1.000

−0.084

−0.065

0.514

0.511

0.614

0.529

Credit

  

1.000

0.115

−0.050

−0.035

−0.062

−0.027

Remittances

   

1.000

0.111

0.072

−0.029

−0.001

FDI

    

1.000

0.749

0.504

0.626

Mobile

     

1.000

0.669

0.649

Internet

      

1.000

0.747

Telephone

       

1.000

IHDI

  1. Credit Private domestic credit, FDI foreign direct investment, Mobile mobile phone penetration, Internet Internet penetration, Telephone telephone penetration, IHDI inequality-adjusted human development index

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Andrés, A.R., Amavilah, V., Asongu, S. (2017). Linkages Between Formal Institutions, ICT Adoption, and Inclusive Human Development in Sub-Saharan Africa. In: Kaur, H., Lechman, E., Marszk, A. (eds) Catalyzing Development through ICT Adoption. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-56523-1_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics