Skip to main content
Log in

Multi-period risk minimization purchasing models for fashion products with interest rate, budget, and profit target considerations

  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Traditionally, in the fashion industry, purchasing decisions for retailers are made based on various factors such as budget, profit target, and interest rate. Since the market demand is highly volatile, risk is inherently present and it is critically important to incorporate risk consideration into the decision making framework. Motivated by the observed industrial practice, we explore via a mean-variance approach the multi-period risk minimization inventory models for fashion product purchasing. We first construct a basic multi-period risk optimization model for the fashion retailer and illustrate how its optimal solution can be determined by solving a simpler problem. Then, we analytically find that the optimal ordering quantity is increasing in the expected profit target, decreasing in the number of periods of the season, and increasing in the market interest rate. After that, we propose and solve several extended models which consider realistic and timely industrial measures such as minimum ordering quantity, carbon emission tax, and carbon quota. We analytically derive the necessary and sufficient condition(s) for the existence of the optimal solution for each model and show how the purchasing budget, the profit target, and the market interest rate affect the optimal solution. Finally, we investigate the supply chain coordination challenge and analytically illustrate how an upstream manufacturer can offer implementable supply contracts to optimize the supply chain.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It means Zara can prepare the new products from the “conceptual design phase” to the “ready-to-sell merchandise phase” in just 15 days.

  2. Since the 1950s, pioneered by the Nobel Laureate Harry Markowitz, the mean-variance framework has been a truly influential theory for risk analysis in finance and beyond (Markowitz 1959). The simplest way to look at the mean-variance framework is that it focuses on two statistics in its analysis, namely the mean and the variance, where we capture the benefit (under uncertainty) by its expected value (the “mean”) and level of risk by the variation of the uncertain benefit (the “variance”). In recent years, the mean-variance framework is widely applied to exploring supply chain management problems. See a recent review by Chiu and Choi (2013) for more discussions.

  3. This follows the fast fashion industrial practice. In addition, it helps to avoid product cannibalization effect.

  4. Notice that for the iid assumption: The “identical” part follows from the fact that the products belong to the same product category, while the “independent” part is critical for us to derive analytical insights in the paper. As a remark, if we consider the more general situation (e.g., demands across periods are not iid), the multi-period problems in general will not be decomposable into simpler single period problems, and methods such as dynamic programming cannot be applied directly. In such a case, we can consider employing the indirect optimization method as proposed by Li et al. (2002) and employed by Choi et al. (2011) to explore the problem. The basic idea of their approach is to develop a separable problem, called an auxiliary problem, which can be solved by multi-period dynamic programming. After that, they identify the conditions under which the solutions of the original problem and the auxiliary problem converge. Observe that by their proposed indirect optimization approach, despite being a feasible one to solve the problem, no closed-form solution can be obtained for further analytical investigation.

  5. Notice that it is an industrial practice for this kind of fashion purchasing problem to have the same quantity for each product under the same product category. This basically relates to quantity discount as well as minimum ordering quantity issues in which the manufacturer will negotiate with the retailer. If the retailer asks for different quantity for each product within the same product category in the same season, it complicates the contract terms and is not “welcome” and practical. Thus, a common practice is to have the same quantity for each product under the same product category in the same season.

  6. If we consider the case when the product purchasing fee is paid to the supplier when the period starts, the present value of this cost (for this period) for the retailer is cq. If the purchasing fee is paid at the end of the period, the present value of this cost (for this period) \(\tilde{c} =cq /(1 +i)\). Either arrangement will not complicate the analysis and will yield a similar result by just a simple parameter substitution.

  7. Notice that the markdown money contract and the returns policy (Li et al. 2012b) are both commonly adopted in the fashion industry and they are very similar. See Tsay (2002) for some more discussions on the differences between them.

  8. Notice that in this section, we do not explicitly mention why the manufacturer wishes to coordinate the supply chain. In fact, there are two important reasons. First, the manufacturer can establish a more competitive and efficient supply chain upon channel coordination is achieved. Second, it is well noted that by definition the coordinated supply chain possesses the highest (expected) profit. Thus, the total amount of (expected) profit in the supply chain under coordination must be higher than the scenario when the supply chain is not coordinated. In other words, there exists a supply chain profit surplus which is defined as the positive difference between the profits of the coordinated and the uncoordinated supply chains. As a result, after finding a way to coordinate the supply chain, the manufacturer and the retailer can then make an arrangement to further split the supply chain profit surplus. For instance, by a simple fixed credit transfer policy which implies that the manufacturer can always get better off when the supply chain is coordinated.

References

  • Agrawal, V., & Seshadri, S. (2000). Risk intermediation in supply chains. IIE Transactions, 32, 819–831.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anvari, M. (1987). Optimality criteria and risk in inventory models: the case of the newsboy problem. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 38, 625–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. A. (1979). Incentives, uncertainty, and risk in the newsboy problem. Decision Sciences, 10, 341–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. (2003). Supply chain coordination with contracts. In S. Graves & T. de Kok (Eds.), Handbooks in operations research and management science: supply chain management. (pp. 229–340). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caliskan-Demirag, O., & Chen, Y. (2011). Customer and retailer rebates under risk aversion. International Journal of Production Economics, 133, 736–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, F., & Federgruen, A. (2000). Mean-variance analysis of basic inventory models. Working paper, Columbia University.

  • Chen, Y. J., & Seshari, S. (2005). Supply chain structure and demand risk. Automatica, 42, 1291–1299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y. F., & Yano, C. A. (2010). Improving supply chain performance and managing risk under weather-related demand uncertainty. Management Science, 56, 1380–1397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, C. K., Hung, T. W., & Weng, T. C. (2007). A net present value approach in developing optimal replenishment policies for a product life cycle. Applied Mathematics and Computation, 184, 360–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, C. H., & Choi, T. M. (2010). Optimal pricing and stocking decisions for newsvendor problem with value-at-risk consideration. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man and Cybernetics. Part A. Systems and Humans, 40, 1116–1119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, C. H., & Choi, T. M. (2013). Supply chain risk analysis with mean-variance models: a technical review. Annals of Operations Research. doi:10.1007/s10479-013-1386-4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, C. H., Choi, T. M., & Li, D. (2009). Price wall or war: the pricing strategies for retailers. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man and Cybernetics. Part A. Systems and Humans, 39, 331–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiu, C. H., Choi, T. M., & Li, X. (2011). Supply chain coordination with risk sensitive agent under target sales rebate contracts. Automatica, 47, 1617–1625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, S., & Ruszczynski, A. (2011). A multi-product risk-averse newsvendor with exponential utility function. European Journal of Operational Research, 214, 78–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M. (2007). Pre-season stocking and pricing decisions for fashion retailers with multiple information updating. International Journal of Production Economics, 106, 146–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M., & Chiu, C. H. (2012). Mean-downside-risk and mean-variance newsvendor models: implications for sustainable fashion retailing. International Journal of Production Economics, 135, 552–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M., Li, D., & Yan, H. (2008a). Mean-variance analysis of a single supplier and retailer supply chain under a returns policy. European Journal of Operational Research, 184, 356–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M., Li, D., & Yan, H. (2008b). Mean-variance analysis for the newsvendor problem. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man and Cybernetics. Part A. Systems and Humans, 38, 1169–1180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M., Chiu, C. H., & Fu, P. (2011). Periodic review multi-period inventory control under a mean-variance optimization objective. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man and Cybernetics. Part A. Systems and Humans, 41, 678–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eeckhoudt, L., Gollier, C., & Schlesinger, H. (1995). The risk-averse (and prudent) newsboy. Management Science, 41, 786–794.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, M., & Raman, A. (1996). Reducing the cost of demand uncertainty through accurate response to early sales. Operations Research, 44, 87–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, M., Rajaram, K., & Raman, A. (2001). Optimizing inventory replenishment of retail fashion products. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 3, 230–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gan, X., Sethi, S. P., & Yan, H. (2004). Coordination of supply chains with risk-averse agents. Production and Operations Management, 13, 135–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gan, X., Sethi, S. P., & Yan, H. (2005). Channel coordination with a risk-neutral supplier and a downside-risk-averse retailer. Production and Operations Management, 14, 80–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Govindan, K., & Sasikumar, P. (2009). Developing the reverse logistics network—a comment and suggestions on minimizing the reverse logistics cost. Omega, 37, 741.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Govindan, K., Haq, A. N., & Devika, M. (2009). Analysis of closed loop supply chain using genetic algorithm and particle swarm optimization. International Journal of Production Research, 47, 1175–1200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubbström, R. W., & Thorstenson, A. (1986). Evaluation of capital costs in a multi-level inventory system by means of the annuity stream principle. European Journal of Operational Research, 24, 136–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, R. M., & Pakkala, T. P. M. (2005). A discounted cash flow approach to the base stock inventory model. International Journal of Production Economics, 93–94, 439–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, Z., Lee, C. K. M., & Nie, X. (2012). Proactive and reactive purchasing planning under dependent demand, price and yield risks. Working paper, Nanyang Technological University.

  • Hsieh, C. C., & Lu, Y. T. (2010). Manufacturer’s return policy in a two-stage supply chain with two risk-averse retailers and random demand. European Journal of Operational Research, 207, 514–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inderfurth, K., & Schefer, R. (1996). Analysis of order-up-to-S inventory policies under cash flow market value maximization. International Journal of Production Economics, 46–47, 323–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jammernegg, W., & Kischka, P. (2012). Newsvendor problems with VaR and CVaR consideration. In T. M. Choi (Ed.), Handbook of newsvendor problems: models, extensions and applications (pp. 197–216). New York: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Jornsten, K., Nonas, S. L., Sandal, L., & Uboe, J. (2012). Transfer of risk in the newsvendor model with discrete demand. Omega, 40, 404–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau, H. S. (1980). The newsboy problem under alternative optimization objectives. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 31, 525–535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau, H. S., & Lau, A. H. L. (1999). Manufacturer’s pricing strategy and returns policy for a single-period commodity. European Journal of Operational Research, 116, 291–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, D., Qian, F., & Fu, P. (2002). Variance minimization approach for a class of dual control problems. IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, 47, 2010–2020.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, X., Li, Y., & Cai, X. (2012a). Quantity decisions in a supply chain with early returns remanufacturing. International Journal of Production Research, 50, 2161–2173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y., Wei, C., & Cai, X. (2012b). Optimal pricing and order policies with B2B product returns for fashion products. International Journal of Production Economics, 135, 637–646.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Z., & Nagurney, A. (2011). Supply chain outsourcing under exchange rate risk and competition. Omega, 39, 539–549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma, L., Xue, W., Zhao, Y., & Lin, X. (2013). Loss-averse inventory and borrowing decisions with constraints on working capital in fashion and textiles industry. Mathematical Problems in Engineering. Article ID 657641. doi:10.1155/2013/657641.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. M. (1959). Portfolio selection: efficient diversification of investment. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-de-Albeniz, V., & Simchi-Levi, D. (2006). Mean-variance trade-offs in supply contracts. Naval Research Logistics, 53, 603–616.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mousavi, S. M., Hajipour, V., Niaki, S. T. A., & Alikar, N. (2013). Optimizing multi-item multi-period inventory control system with discounted cash flow and inflation: two calibrated meta-heuristic algorithms. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 37, 2241–2256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mukhopadhyay, S. K., Zhu, X., & Yue, X. (2008). Optimal contract design for mixed channels under information asymmetry. Production and Operations Management, 17, 641–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, D. L., & Wu, D. D. (2011). Risk management models for supply chain: a scenario analysis of outsourcing to China. Supply Chain Management, 16, 401–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sankarasubramanian, E., & Kumaraswamy, S. (1983). Optimal ordering quantity for pre-determined level of profit. Management Science, 29, 512–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shen, B., Choi, T. M., Wang, Y., & Lo, C. K. Y. (2013). Coordination of fashion supply chains with risk averse supplier by markdown money policy. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man and Cybernetics. Part A. Systems and Humans, 43, 266–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sodhi, M. S., & Tang, C. S. (2012). Managing supply chain risk. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Song, J., & Leng, M. (2012). Analysis of the single-period problem under carbon emission policies. In T. M. Choi (Ed.), Handbook of newsvendor problems: models, extensions and applications (pp. 297–314). New York: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Tsay, A. A. (2002). Risk sensitivity in distribution channel partnerships: implications for manufacturer return policies. Journal of Retailing, 78, 147–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaagen, H., & Wallace, S. W. (2008). Product variety arising from hedging in the fashion supply chains. International Journal of Production Economics, 114, 431–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Laan, E. (2003). An NPV and AC analysis of a stochastic inventory system with joint manufacturing and remanufacturing. International Journal of Production Economics, 81–82, 317–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei, Y., & Choi, T. M. (2010). Mean-variance analysis of supply chains under wholesale pricing and profit sharing scheme. European Journal of Operational Research, 204, 255–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, D. D., & Olson, D. (2010). Enterprise risk management: a DEA VaR approach in vendor selection. International Journal of Production Research, 48, 4919–4932.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, J., Li, J., Wang, S., & Cheng, T. C. E. (2009). Mean–variance analysis of the newsvendor model with stockout cost. Omega, 37, 724–730.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, M. F. (2010). Supply chain integrated inventory model with present value and dependent crashing cost is polynomial. Mathematical and Computer Modelling, 51, 802–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, G., Ronald, R. J., & Chu, P. (2005). Inventory models with variable lead time and present value. European Journal of Operational Research, 164, 358–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, D., Xu, H., & Wu, Y. (2009). Single and multi-period optimal inventory control models with risk-averse constraints. European Journal of Operational Research, 199, 420–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu, X., Mukhopadhyay, S. K., & Yue, X. (2011). Role of forecast effort on supply chain profitability under various information sharing scenarios. International Journal of Production Economics, 129, 284–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tsan-Ming Choi.

Additional information

This research is partially supported by Research Grants Council of Hong Kong under the grant number PolyU5420-10H. The author sincerely thanks the constructive and important comments by the editor and two anonymous reviewers. He also expresses his hearty thanks to Hau-Ling Chan for her comments on the earlier draft of this paper.

Appendix: All Proofs

Appendix: All Proofs

Proof of Lemma 3.1

From (3.6a), (3.6b), (3.6c), we have Problem (BP-1) given as follows,

$$\begin{aligned} &\min_{q}\quad V \Biggl( \sum_{k = 1}^{N} \frac{\pi_{_{R,k}}(q)}{(1 + i)^{k}} \Biggr) \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)
$$\begin{aligned} &s.t.\quad\ \, E \Biggl( \sum_{k = 1}^{N} \frac{\pi_{_{R,k}}(q)}{(1 + i)^{k}} \Biggr) \ge T_{\sum} \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)
$$\begin{aligned} &\hphantom{\min_{q}}\quad \sum_{k = 1}^{N} \frac{cq}{(1 + i)^{k}} \le W_{\sum}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

From (3.4) and (3.5), we have \(A(i,N)= \frac{(1 + i)^{N} - 1}{i(1 + i)^{N}}\), and \(B(i,N)= \frac{(1 + i)^{2N} - 1}{(1 + i)^{2N}[(1 + i)^{2} - 1]}\). Put them into (A.1), (A.2) and (A.3) yields (A.4),

$$\begin{aligned} &\min_{q}\quad B(i,N)\hat{\pi}_{R}(q) \\ &s.t.\quad\ \, A(i,N)\bar{\pi}_{R}(q) \ge T_{\sum} \\ &\hphantom{\min_{q}}\quad A(i,N)cq \le W_{\sum}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

It is straight forward to show that (A.4) and Problem (BP-2) are the same.

Problem (BP-2)

$$\begin{aligned} &\min_{q}\quad \hat{\pi}_{R}(q) \end{aligned}$$
(A.5a)
$$\begin{aligned} &s.t.\quad\ \, \bar{\pi}_{R}(q) \ge T_{\sum} /A(i,N) \end{aligned}$$
(A.5b)
$$\begin{aligned} &\hphantom{\min_{q}}\quad cq \le W_{\sum} /A(i,N). \end{aligned}$$
(A.5c)

Thus, Problems (BP-1) and (BP-2) are equivalent, and the optimal solution for the original basic Problem (BP-1) is the same as the one for Problem (BP-2). □

Proof of Proposition 3.2

By definition in (3.9), we have \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) = \arg_{q \in [0,q_{R,E^{*}}]} [\bar{\pi}_{R}(q) = T_{\sum} /A(i,N)]\). Notice that: (i) \(d\hat{\pi}_{R}(q)/dq > 0\) and hence the objective function \(\hat{\pi}_{R}(q)\) [P.S.: (A.5a)] is an increasing function of q, (ii\() \bar{\pi}_{R}(q\)) is a concave function of q and it is increasing \(\forall q \in [0,q_{R,E^{*}}]\). Thus, if \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) \le W_{\sum} /[cA(i,N)]\)[constraint (A.5c)] holds, the optimal solution for Problem (BP-2) is given by \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} )\). If \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) > W_{\sum} /[cA(i,N)]\), \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} )\) violates the purchasing budget constraint (A.5c) and is infeasible. However, since \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} )\) is the minimum ordering quantity which can achieve the expected profit target (A.5b), having a lower quantity will violate the expected profit target constraint and is hence infeasible. As a consequence, we can see that (a) Problem (BP-2), and equivalently Problem (BP-1), has an optimal solution if and only if \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{cA(i,N)}\). (b) If \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{cA(i,N)}\), the optimal ordering quantity for every period is equal to \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} )\). □

Proof of Corollary 3.3

From Proposition 3.2, we know that the necessary and sufficient condition for the existence of solution for Problem (BP-1) is given by\(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{ cA(i,N)}\). From it, we can see that \(\frac{W_{\sum}}{cA(i,N)}\) will get larger if the purchasing budget W is larger, and \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} )\) will get smaller if the expected profit target T is smaller. These two situations both increase the likelihood that \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{cA(i,N)}\) will be satisfied. We thus have Corollary 3.3. □

Proof of Corollary 3.4

If the optimal ordering quantity of Problem (BP-1) exists (when the condition in Proposition 3.2a holds), the optimal solution is given by \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} )\). By definition, we have \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) = \arg_{q \in [0,q_{R,E^{*}}]}[\bar{\pi}_{R}(q) = T_{\sum} /A(i,N)]\). From the analytical expression, it is obvious that \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} )\) is: (a) increasing in the expected profit target T ,(b) decreasing in the number of periods of the season N, and (c) increasing in the market interest rate i. □

Proof of Proposition 4.1

Problem (MP) extends Problem (BP-1) by including a constraint on MOQ.

From Proposition 3.2, we notice that Problem (BP-1) and Problem (BP-2) are equivalent. As such, we can rewrite Problem (MP) as Problem (MP-2) in the following,

Problem (MP-2)

$$\begin{aligned} &\min_{q}\quad \hat{\pi}_{R}(q) \end{aligned}$$
(A.6a)
$$\begin{aligned} &s.t.\quad\ \, \bar{\pi}_{R}(q) \ge T_{\sum} /A(i,N) \end{aligned}$$
(A.6b)
$$\begin{aligned} &\hphantom{\min_{q}}\quad cq \le W_{\sum} /A(i,N) \end{aligned}$$
(A.6c)
$$\begin{aligned} &\hphantom{\min_{q}}\quad q \ge q_{MOQ}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.6d)

Define:

$$ Q_{MOQ}(T_{\sum} ) = \max \bigl(q_{R,BP^*}(T_{\sum} ),q_{MOQ}\bigr). $$
(A.7)
$$ q_{R,MP2^*} = \textrm{the optimal ordering quantity for Problem (MP-2)}. $$
(A.8)

Notice that following the same argument as in the proof of Proposition 3.2, Problem (MP-2) has an optimal solution if and only if \(Q_{MOQ}(T_{\sum} ) \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{cA(i,N)}\), which relates to constraint (A.6c). If this necessary and sufficient condition holds, we have two cases, namely Case (i) \(q_{MOQ} \le q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{cA(i,N)}\), and Case (ii) \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) < q_{MOQ} \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{ cA(i,N)}\). This completes the proof for part (a).

For parts (b) and (c), as we discussed in the proof of Proposition 3.2, since the objective function (A.6a) aims at minimizing risk and \(\hat{\pi}_{R}(q)\) is an increasing function of q, the optimal q is the smallest possible q which satisfies all the constraints. As such, we have:

  • For Case (i): If \(q_{MOQ} \le q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{ cA(i,N)}\), then \(q_{R,MP2^{*}} = q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} )\).

  • For Case (ii): If \(q_{R,BP^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) < q_{MOQ} \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{ cA(i,N)}\), then \(q_{R,MP2^{*}} = q_{MOQ}\).

Since Problem (MP-2) and Problem (MP) have the same optimal solution, we have: \(q_{R,MP2^{*}}= q_{R,MP^{*}}\), which implies Proposition 4.1(b) and Proposition 4.1(c). □

Proof of Corollary 4.2

(a) Following the same logic and argument as in the proof of Corollary 3.4. (b) A direct result from Proposition 4.1(c). □

Proof of Lemma 5.1

By definition, we have \(\bar{\pi}_{R}(q)= (p - c)q - (p - v)\int_{0}^{q} F(x)dx\),

$$\hat{\pi}_{R}(q)= (p - v)^{2}\xi (q),\qquad \bar{ \pi}_{R,TAX}(q)= (p - c - t)q - (p - v)\int_{0}^{q} F(x)dx,\quad \mbox{and } $$

\(\hat{\pi}_{R,TAX}(q) = (p - v)^{2}\xi (q)\). Directly comparing them implies that for any fixed quantity q and carbon emission tax t>0, we have: (a\()\bar{\pi}_{R,TAX}(q) < \bar{\pi}_{R}(q\)) and (b\()\hat{\pi}_{R,TAX}(q)=\hat{\pi}_{R}(q\)). □

Proof of Proposition 5.2

First of all, similar to the proof for Proposition 3.2, observe that Problem (CP) and Problem (CP-2) below have the same optimal solution.

Problem (CP-2)

$$\begin{aligned} &\min_{q}\quad \hat{\pi}_{R,TAX}(q) \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)
$$\begin{aligned} &s.t.\quad\ \, \bar{\pi}_{R,TAX}(q) \ge T_{\sum} /A(i,N) \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)
$$\begin{aligned} &\hphantom{\min_{q}}\quad (c + t)q \le W_{\sum} /A(i,N) \end{aligned}$$
(A.11)
$$\begin{aligned} &\hphantom{\min_{q}}\quad q \le q_{CQ}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.12)

Define:

$$ q_{R,CP2^*} = \textrm{the optimal ordering quantity for Problem (CP-2)}. $$
(A.13)

It is easy to observe that Problem (CP-2)’s optimal solution \(q_{R,CP2^{*}}\) exists and is equal to \(q_{R,BP,TAX^{*}}(T_{\sum} )\) if and only if \(q_{R,BP,TAX^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{(c + t)A(i,N)}\) and \(q_{R,BP,TAX^{*}}(T_{\sum} ) \le q_{CQ}\). Since, \(q_{R,CP2^{*}}= q_{R,CP^{*}}\), Proposition 5.2 results. □

Proof of Corollary 5.3

Following the same logic and argument as in the proof of Corollary 3.4. For the impact of carbon emission tax t, it is a direct result from Proposition 5.2 and the definition of \(q_{R,BP,TAX^{*}}(T_{\sum} )\). □

Proof of Proposition 6.1

Following the proofs and the results of Proposition 4.1 and Proposition 5.2, Proposition 6.1 is derived. □

Proof of Lemma 7.1

  1. (a)

    First of all, from (7.4), we know that \(q_{SC,TAX^{*}} = \arg \max_{q}E[\sum_{k = 1}^{N} \frac{\pi_{SC,k,TAX}(q)}{(1 + i)^{k}} ]= \arg \{ \max_{q}A(i,N)\bar{\pi}_{SC,TAX}(q)\}=\arg \{ \max_{q}\bar{\pi}_{SC,TAX}(q)\}\). Simple calculus confirms that \(\bar{\pi}_{SC,TAX}(q)\) is a concave function and hence \(q_{SC,TAX^{*}}=\arg_{q}\{ d\bar{\pi}_{SC,TAX}(q)/dq = 0\}= F^{ - 1}[(p - m - t)/(p - v)]\).

  2. (b)

    Since the presence of carbon quota is imposed by the governing body and the whole supply chain will be affected, the best possible quantity cannot exceed q CQ and hence we have \(q_{SC^{*}}=\min \{ q_{SC,TAX^{*}},q_{CQ}\}\).

 □

Proof of Proposition 7.2

By coordination, we aim at making the optimal ordering quantity for Problem (MCP) equal to \(q_{SC^{*}}\). Notice that by definition, we have \(q_{SC^{*}}=\min \{ q_{SC,TAX^{*}},q_{CQ}\}\). Thus, the feasibility condition on \(q_{SC^{*}} \le q_{CQ}\) is implied (and always satisfied). As a result, under the markdown money contract with MOQ =0 (i.e. q MOQ =0), the only feasibility check is \(q_{SC^{*}} \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{(c + t)A(i,N)}\). When \(q_{SC^{*}} \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{(c + t)A(i,N)}\) holds, we have,

$$ q_{R,MM - CP^*}^{MM} = \arg_{q}\biggl\{ (p - c - t)q - (p - v - \alpha )\int_{0}^{q} F(x)dx = T_{\sum} /A(i,N)\biggr\}. $$
(A.14)

With (A.14), we have the following,

$$\begin{aligned} &q_{R,MM - CP^*}^{MM} = q_{SC^*} \\ &\quad {} \Leftrightarrow (p - c - t)q_{SC^*} - (p - v - \alpha )\int _{0}^{q_{SC^*}} F(x)dx = T_{\sum} /A(i,N) \\ &\quad {} \Leftrightarrow \alpha = \alpha^{*} \equiv (p - v) - \biggl( \frac{A(i,N)(p - c - t)q_{SC^*} - T_{\sum}}{A(i,N)\int_{0}^{q_{SC^*}} F(x)dx} \biggr). \end{aligned}$$

 □

Proof of Proposition 7.3

Similar to the proof of Proposition 7.2, observe that by definition, we have \(q_{SC^{*}}=\min \{ q_{SC,TAX^{*}},q_{CQ}\}\). Thus, the feasibility condition on \(q_{SC^{*}} \le q_{CQ}\) is always satisfied. Under the wholesale pricing contract with MOQ =q MOQ , the only feasibility check is \(q_{SC^{*}} \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{(c + t)A(i,N)}\) as q MOQ is a control variable of the manufacturer. When \(q_{SC^{*}} \le \frac{W_{\sum}}{(c + t)A(i,N)}\) holds, according to Proposition 6.1, setting \(q_{MOQ}= q_{SC^{*}}\) can coordinate the supply chain by making \(q_{R,MCP^{*}} = q_{SC^{*}}\). □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Choi, TM. Multi-period risk minimization purchasing models for fashion products with interest rate, budget, and profit target considerations. Ann Oper Res 237, 77–98 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-013-1453-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-013-1453-x

Keywords

Navigation