Skip to main content
Log in

Contract competition between hierarchies, managerial compensation and imperfectly correlated shocks

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze competition through incentive contracts for managers in duopoly. Privately informed managers exert surplus enhancing effort that generates an externality on the rival. Asymmetric information on imperfectly correlated shocks creates a two-way distortion of efforts under strategic substitutability in effort and a double downward distortion under strategic complementarity in effort. In the first case, as with contracts for R&D activity or small contractual spillovers for quantity and price competition, increasing the correlation of types reduces the polarization of contracts and the differentials in managerial compensations between efficient and inefficient managers. In the second case, as with large contractual spillovers, the opposite occurs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Even the relation with external partners, such as exclusive dealers or upstream firms, can be governed by incentive contracts that affect (and are affected by) competition.

  2. The same focus on moral hazard applies in the analysis by Baggs and de Bettignies (2007).

  3. More recently Piccolo and Pagnozzi (2013) have found a two-way distortion in a model of information sharing between competing hierarchies when traded goods are substitutes.

  4. In what follows we assume that the appropriate second order conditions are satisfied.

  5. As is well known, strategic delegation can be used by each firm to affect the equilibrium outcomes, but we will not focus on this issue.

  6. This contracting limitation may be due to problems of verifiability on the other firm’s variables for lack of auditing rights and abilities—see Brainard and Martimort (1996).

  7. The denominator is always positive in case of strategic substitutability. We assume \(\Pi _{12}\left( e_{1}^{*},e_{1}^{*}\right) <g_{ee}\left( \theta _{1},e_{1}^{*}\right) /\lambda -\left( 1/\lambda -1\right) \Pi _{11}\left( e_{1}^{*},e_{2}^{*}\right) -\Pi _{11}\left( e_{1}^{*},e_{1}^{*}\right) \) in case of strategic complementarity. This is easily satisfied in our example.

  8. Biglaiser and Mezzetti (2000) have considered auctions to hire managers in a principal-agent framework. With identical principals, the equilibrium gives all the surplus to each type of worker.

  9. As mentioned before we always assume that firm i’s contract cannot be conditioned on the type of the manager of firm j or, more generally, on messages sent from that firm. The literature on competing mechanisms has investigated equilibria of this kind in different frameworks—see, for a survey, Dittrich and Städter (2015).

  10. More efficient solutions to the moral hazard problem could be reached by changing the ownership structure and selling the right to control to the manager. However wealth constraints make this solution often unrealistic (see Lewis and Sappington 2000, for a general treatment), and we will not consider it here.

  11. For an analysis of alternative bargaining solutions in models with moral hazard see Demougin and Helm (2006) and Dittrich and Städter (2015).

  12. As is well known, d’Aspremont and Gerard-Varet (1979) introduced Bayesian implementation. See Ledyard and Palfrey (1999) for a modern treatment on public goods.

  13. We can check later that the solution is monotonic, which guarantees global incentive compatibility. There is no need for a modified monotonicity condition as in Piccolo et al. (2008) because here incentives constraint are not modified by contract competition.

  14. However, if goods are complements, strategic complementarity between efforts emerges.

  15. Again, we exclude the possibility of conditioning contracts on messages from the other manager. As is well known since Crémer and McLean (1985), this would allow principals to exploit correlation in a more efficient way - see Bertoletti and Poletti (1997) and Laffont and Martimort (2000) for related applications. However, in our context, contracts based on effort of other managers do not appear realistic.

  16. The generalized slopes \(h_{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{2},\theta _{1},\alpha \right) \) and \(f_{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\alpha \right) \) satisfy \( \left| h_{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{2},\theta _{1},\alpha \right) \right| >\left| f_{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\alpha \right) \right| \). Notice that \(f_{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\overline{\alpha } \right) =0\) and \(h_{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{2},\theta _{1},\overline{\alpha } \right) \rightarrow \infty \).

  17. See Peters (2014) on competing mechanisms and the classic work by Laffont and Tirole Laffont and Tirole (1993) and the recent one by Calzolari and Scarpa (2012) on regulated firms with asymmetric information.

  18. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for suggesting the proofs by contradiction.

References

  • Aggarwal RK, Samwick AA (1999) The other side of the trade-off: the impact of risk on executive compensation. J Polit Econ 107(1):65–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aggarwal RK, Samwick AA (1999) Executive compensation, strategic competition, and relative performance evaluation: theory and evidence’. J Financ 54(6):1999–2043

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baggs J, de Bettignies J-E (2007) Product market competition an agency costs. J Ind Econ 55(2):289–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron D, Myerson R (1982) Regulating a monopolist with unknown costs. Econometrica 50(4):911–930

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim BD, Whinston MD (1986) Common Agency. Econom 54(4):923–942

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoletti P, EtroF (2016) Preferences, entry and market structure. RAND J Econ (in press)

  • Bertoletti P, Poletti C (1997) X-inefficiency, competition and market information. J Ind Econ 45(4):359–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biglaiser G, Mezzetti C (2000) Incentive auctions and information revelation. RAND J Econ 31(1):145–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brainard SL, Martimort D (1996) Strategic Trade policy design with asymmetric information and public contracts. Rev Econ Stud 63:81–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calzolari G, Scarpa C (2012) On regulation and competition: pros and cons of a diversified monopolist, WP 55, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei

  • Crémer J, McLean RP (1985) Optimal selling strategies under uncertainty for a discriminating monopolist when demands are interdependent. Econometrica 53(2):345–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont C, Gerard-Varet C (1979) Incentives and incomplete information. J Public Econ 11(1):25–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demougin D, Helm C (2006) Moral hazard and bargaining power. Germ Econ Rev 7(4):463–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dittrich M, Städter M (2015) Moral hazard and bargaining over incentive contracts. Res Econ 69(1):75–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Etro F (2011) Endogenous Market structures and contract theory: delegation, principal-agent contracts, screening, franchising and tying. Eur Econ Rev 55(4):463–479

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Etro F, Cella M (2013) Equilibrium principal-agent contracts: competition and R&D incentives. J Econ Manag Strat 22(3):488–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix X, Landier A (2008) Why has CEO pay increased so much? Q J Econ 123:49–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econ J 39:41–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen M, Murphy K (1990) Performance pay and top-management incentives. J Polit Econ 98(2):225–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karuna C (2007) Industry product market competition and managerial incentives. J Account Econ 43(2–3):275–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont J-J, Martimort D (2000) Mechanism design with collusion and correlation. Econometrica 68(2):309–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont J-J, Tirole J (1993) A theory of incentives in procurement and regulation. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont J-J, Tirole J (1986) Using cost observation to regulate firms. J Polit Econ 94(3):614–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear (2015) The impatient salesperson and the delegation of pricing authority. Res Econ 69(1):63–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ledyard J, Palfrey TR (1999) A characterization of interim efficiency with public goods. Econometrica 67(2):435–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis TR, Sappington DEM (1989) Countervailing incentives in agency problems. J Econ Theory 49(2):294–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis TR, Sappington DEM (2000) Motivating wealth-constrained actors. Am Econ Rev 90(4):944–960

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martimort D (1996) Exclusive dealing, common agency, and multiprincipal incentive theory. RAND J Econ 27(1):1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy KJ (1999) Executive compensation. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 38. Elsevier, Oxford, pp 2485–2563

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson RB (1982) Optimal coordination mechanisms in generalized principal-agent problems. J Math Econ 10(1):67–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peters M (2014) Competing mechanisms. Can J Econ 47(2):373–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piccolo S, D’Amato M, Martina R (2008) Product market competition and organizational slack under profit-target contracts. Int J Ind Org 26:1389–1406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piccolo S, Pagnozzi M (2013) Information sharing between vertical hierarchies. Games Econ Behav 79:201–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen S (1981) The economics of superstars. Am Econ Rev 71(5):845–858

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michela Cella.

Additional information

We are thankful to the Editor Giacomo Corneo, and Patrick Rey, Giacomo Calzolari, Salvatore Piccolo, Elena Manzoni, Giovanna Iannantuoni, seminar participants at CSEF (Naples), participants at SAET 2011 (Faro, Portugal), SfED 2011 (Montreal, Canada) and in particular to two referees for useful comments.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

To prove \(e_{1}^{*}\ge e_{2}^{*}\) assume, by contradiction, that the opposite holds, that is \(e_{1}^{*}<e_{2}^{*}\).Footnote 18 Then, since \(g_{e\theta }>0\) and \(g_{ee\theta }\ge 0\) by A.1., it must be that:

$$\begin{aligned} g_{e}\left( \theta _{1},e_{1}^{*}\right) <g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{1}^{*}\right) \le g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}^{*}\right) \end{aligned}$$

Moreover, since \(\Pi _{11}\le 0\), it must be that:

$$\begin{aligned} g_{e}\left( \theta _{1},e_{1}^{*}\right)= & {} \lambda \Pi _{1}\left( e_{1}^{*},e_{1}^{*}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{1}^{*},e_{2}^{*}\right) \\\ge & {} \lambda \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2}^{*},e_{1}^{*}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2}^{*},e_{2}^{*}\right) =g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}^{*}\right) \end{aligned}$$

which contradicts the previous inequality.

Proof of Proposition 2

To prove \(e_{1}\ge e_{2}\) assume, by contradiction, that the opposite holds, that is \(e_{1}<e_{2}\). Then, since \( g_{e\theta }>0\) and \(g_{ee\theta }\ge 0\) by A.1, it must be that:

$$\begin{aligned} g_{e}\left( \theta _{1},e_{1}\right) <g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{1}\right) \le g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}\right) \end{aligned}$$

which implies:

$$\begin{aligned} g_{e}\left( \theta _{1},e_{1}\right) <g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}\right) + \frac{\lambda }{1-\lambda }\Phi _{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) \end{aligned}$$

Moreover, since \(\Pi _{11}\le 0\), it must be that:

$$\begin{aligned} g_{e}\left( \theta _{1},e_{1}\right)= & {} \lambda \Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{1}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) \\&\quad \ge&\lambda \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{1}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) =g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}\right) + \frac{\lambda }{1-\lambda }\Phi _{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) \end{aligned}$$

which contradicts the previous inequality.

Proof of Proposition 3

Let us consider the following system:

$$\begin{aligned} F(e_{1},e_{2})\equiv & {} \lambda \Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{1}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) -g_{e}\left( \theta _{1},e_{1}\right) =0, \\ H(e_{1},e_{2})\equiv & {} \lambda \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{1}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) -g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}\right) -\frac{\lambda \mu \Phi _{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) }{1-\lambda }=0 \end{aligned}$$

which defines \(\left( e_{1}^{*},e_{2}^{*}\right) \) if \(\mu =0\) and \( \left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) \) if \(\mu =1\). Applying the Cramer rule we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{de_{1}}{d\mu }=\frac{\frac{\partial F}{\partial e_{2}}\frac{\partial H }{\partial \mu }-\frac{\partial F}{\partial \mu }\frac{\partial H}{\partial e_{2}}}{\Delta }=\frac{-\lambda \Phi _{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) \Pi _{12}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) }{\Delta } \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta\equiv & {} \frac{\partial F}{\partial e_{1}}\frac{\partial H}{\partial e_{2}}-\frac{\partial F}{\partial e_{2}}\frac{\partial H}{\partial e_{1}}= \frac{\partial F}{\partial e_{1}}\frac{\partial H}{\partial e_{1}}\left[ f_{e}\left( e,\theta \right) -h_{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{2},\theta _{1}\right) \right] \\ \frac{\partial F}{\partial e_{1}}= & {} \lambda \Pi _{11}\left( e_{1},e_{1}\right) +\lambda \Pi _{12}\left( e_{1},e_{1}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{11}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) -g_{ee}\left( \theta _{1},e_{1}\right)<0\\ \frac{\partial H}{\partial e_{2}}= & {} \lambda \Pi _{11}\left( e_{2},e_{1}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{11}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{12}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) \\&\quad -g_{ee}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}\right) -\frac{\lambda \Phi _{ee}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) }{1-\lambda }<0\\ \frac{\partial F}{\partial e_{2}}= & {} \left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{12}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) \lessgtr 0\text { if }\Pi _{12}\lessgtr 0\\ \frac{\partial H}{\partial e_{1}}= & {} \lambda \Pi _{12}\left( e_{2},e_{1}\right) \lessgtr 0\text { if }\Pi _{12}\lessgtr 0 \end{aligned}$$

Notice that for any \(\theta _{2}>\theta _{1}\) we have \(\Phi _{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) >0\) by A.1 and \(\Delta >0\) by A.2, therefore:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{de_{1}}{d\mu }\gtrless 0\quad \text { if }\quad \Pi _{12}\lessgtr 0. \end{aligned}$$

Analogously, we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{de_{2}}{d\mu }=\frac{\frac{\partial H}{\partial e_{1}}\frac{\partial F }{\partial \mu }-\frac{\partial H}{\partial \mu }\frac{\partial F}{\partial e_{1}}}{\Delta }=\frac{\lambda \Phi _{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) \frac{\partial F}{\partial e_{1}}}{\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Delta }<0 \end{aligned}$$

Then, the introduction of asymmetric information with \(\Phi _{e}>0\) implies \( e_{1}>e_{1}^{*}\) and \(e_{2}<e_{2}^{*}\) (the two-way distortion) under strategic substitutability, and \(\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) <\left( e_{1},e_{2}^{*}\right) \) (double downward distortion) under strategic complementarity.

Proof of Proposition 4

To characterize the comparative statics of the equilibrium effort levels \(\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) \) with respect to \( \alpha \) when \(\Pi _{12}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) <0\) we totally differentiate the equilibrium system:

$$\begin{aligned} F(e_{1},e_{2},\alpha )\equiv & {} \left( \lambda +\frac{\alpha }{\lambda }\right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{1}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda -\frac{\alpha }{\lambda } \right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) -g_{e}\left( \theta _{1},e_{1}\right) =0,\\ H(e_{1},e_{2},\alpha )\equiv & {} \left( \lambda -\frac{\alpha }{1-\lambda } \right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{1}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda +\frac{\alpha }{ 1-\lambda }\right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) \\&-g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}\right) -\frac{\lambda \Phi _{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) }{1-\lambda }=0 \end{aligned}$$

and apply the Cramer rule as before to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{de_{1}}{d\alpha }=\frac{\frac{\partial F}{\partial e_{2}}\frac{ \partial H}{\partial \alpha }-\frac{\partial F}{\partial \alpha }\frac{ \partial H}{\partial e_{2}}}{\Delta }<0 \end{aligned}$$

where again \(\Delta >0\) by A.2. Under strategic substitutability we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial F}{\partial e_{2}}= & {} \left( 1-\lambda -\frac{\alpha }{\lambda } \right) \Pi _{12}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right)<0,\\ \frac{\partial H}{\partial \alpha }= & {} \frac{\Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) -\Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{1}\right) }{1-\lambda }>0,\\ \frac{\partial F}{\partial \alpha }= & {} \frac{\Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{1}\right) -\Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) }{\lambda }<0,\\ \frac{\partial H}{\partial e_{2}}= & {} \left( \lambda -\frac{\alpha }{1-\lambda } \right) \Pi _{11}\left( e_{2},e_{1}\right) + \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1-\lambda +\frac{\alpha }{1-\lambda }\right) \left[ \Pi _{11}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) +\Pi _{12}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) \right] -g_{ee}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}\right) -\frac{\lambda \Phi _{ee}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) }{1-\lambda }<0 \end{aligned}$$

because \(\Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) >\Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{1}\right) \) and \(\Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) >\Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{1}\right) \). Analogously we have \(de_{2}/d\alpha >0\).

Proof of Proposition 5

To compare extreme effort levels under the assumption \(\Pi _{12}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) >0\), let us consider the effort of the efficient manager first. Notice that \(e_{1}(0)=e_{1}\) as defined in (24):

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda \Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{1}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) =g_{e}\left( \theta _{1},e_{1}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

and \(e_{1}(\overline{\alpha })=e_{11}\) as defined in (13 ):

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{1}\left( e_{11},e_{11}\right) =g_{e}\left( \theta _{1},e_{11}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Strategic complementarity and \(e_{1}>e_{2}\) imply \(\Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{1}\right) >\Pi _{1}\left( e_{1},e_{2}\right) \) and therefore \(e_{1}( \overline{\alpha })=e_{11}>e_{1}(0)=e_{1}\).

Consider the effort of the inefficient manager now. Notice that \( e_{2}(0)=e_{2}\) as defined in (25):

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{1}\right) +\left( 1-\lambda \right) \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) =g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}\right) +\frac{ \lambda }{1-\lambda }\Phi _{e}\left( e_{2},\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

while \(e_{2}(\overline{\alpha })\) must satisfy:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{1}\left( e_{2}(\overline{\alpha }),e_{2}(\overline{\alpha })\right) =g_{e}\left( \theta _{2},e_{2}(\overline{\alpha })\right) +\frac{\lambda }{ 1-\lambda }\Phi _{e}\left( e_{2}(\overline{\alpha }),\theta _{1},\theta _{2}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

For any \(e_{1}>e_{2}\) strategic complementarity implies \(\Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{1}\right) >\Pi _{1}\left( e_{2},e_{2}\right) \), therefore \( e_{2}=e_{2}(0)>e_{2}(\overline{\alpha })\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cella, M., Etro, F. Contract competition between hierarchies, managerial compensation and imperfectly correlated shocks. J Econ 118, 193–218 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-016-0472-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-016-0472-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation